|
Extracts from - * Reserve Bank Research Discussion Paper dated June 1992; and * 'Background information re the increasing interest rate spread for Credit Cards' LOAN RATE STICKINESS: THEORY AND EVIDENCE - RBA 1992 (by Philip Lowe and Thomas Rohling) noted that the Reserve Bank regulated lending interest rates until 1985 and post-deregulation lending interest rates, in particular Credit Card interest rates, did not fall in line with the Overnight Cash Rate, and when falls were passed on, it wasn't done quickly or completely, whereas when the Overnight Cash Rate increased, these increases were passed on by way of higher lending interest rate and more quickly. Hence, credit cards interest rates were particularly sticky when the Overnight Cash Rate fell, as Credit Card interest rates regularly remained 'stuck'.
Financial deregulation in the 1980s saw the lifting of
regulations on interest rates charged by banks.
In general, lending rates now
respond more quickly to changes in banks' cost of funds than they did in
the regulated period. However, lending rates still do not always
move one for one with changes in banks' marginal cost of raising funds.
This paper canvasses four theoretical explanations, other than
collusive behaviour, for loan rate stickiness. These theories are based on - Using regression analysis, we also examine the degree of stickiness of Australian interest rates on secured and unsecured personal loans, credit cards, small and large business overdrafts, and housing loans. We find significant differences in the degree of interest rate stickiness among the different rates, even after allowing for lags in adjustment. The rate on credit cards is found to be the most sticky, followed by personal loan rates, the housing loan rate and the small business overdraft rate. The large business overdraft rate is found to adjust one for one with banks' marginal cost of funds. We briefly examine the behaviour of selected U.S., U.K. and Canadian interest rates. The general order and magnitude of interest rate stickiness is similar to that found for Australia. Although it is not possible to empirically discriminate between the different theories of loan rate stickiness, we interpret the results as providing strong evidence for the switching cost explanation. In addition, implicit risk sharing probably plays an important role in the stickiness of the housing loan rate. 1. INTRODUCTION In contrast to the bulk of studies on interest rate stickiness, we examine the behaviour of a number of different Australian lending rates. These include the rates on housing loans, secured and unsecured personal loans, business loans and credit cards.
The empirical literature on price stickiness in banking has typically focused on a single deposit or lending rate. Yet, casual observation suggests considerable variation in the degree of interest rate stickiness across different products. The interest rate charged on credit cards remains constant for long periods of time while the rate charged on overdrafts changes regularly. In this section we formally examine interest rates on a number of different types of bank loans and, by examining differences in the degree of loan rate stickiness, draw some tentative inferences concerning the cause of the stickiness. 3.1 Data and Estimation Procedure "In the case of overdrafts the maximum rate on all overdrafts was set by the Reserve Bank prior to February 1972". At that time interest rates on overdrafts drawn on limits over $50,000 became a matter for negotiation between the banks and their customers while those drawn under limits less than $50,000 remained regulated. In February 1976 the threshold level was increased to $100,000 and in April 1985 all regulations were lifted. From 1966, when personal loans were introduced, the maximum rate that banks could charge was set by the Reserve Bank. Once again, in April 1985, the controls were removed. At the same time, the maximum interest rate that could be charged on credit cards was deregulated. Prior to this time the maximum rate had been set at 18 per cent per annum. The period of housing loan rate regulation extended beyond that for the other lending rates. Until 1973, the maximum rate that could be charged on housing loans was the same as that on overdrafts although banks typically charged a lower rate. In October 1973 banks agreed to a "consultative maximum" on housing loans which was below the overdraft rate. This was formalised in December 1980 when the maximum rate that could be charged on owner-occupied housing was set one percent below the maximum overdraft rate. The ceiling on new owner-occupied housing loans was finally removed in April 1986. TABLE 2 : TEST OF EQUALITY OF COEFFICIENTS: POST DEREGULATIONFor the housing, credit cards and personal loan rates, the ranking in terms of the degree of stickiness is maintained. Even after nine lags are included the sum of the coefficients on all three of these rates remain significantly less than one. The same is true for the standard overdraft rate. TABLE 3: TEST OF LAG SIGNIFICANCE: POST DEREGULATION In contrast, the rates on personal loans and credit cards do not appear to be more flexible in the deregulated period. 4. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS This paper examines the degree of price stickiness in the market for bank loans. In the classical world of perfect competition, changes in marpal costs are translated into similar changes in the price of the product. We find that complete pass-through of changes in banks' marginal cost of funds only occurs with the base or reference overdraft rates to large and small business borrowers. For credit cards, personal loans, owner-occupied housing loans and the standard overdraft rate, changes in the banks' marginal cost of funds have not been translated one for one into the contemporaneous lending rates. |
|
|