Phil Hanratty - Economics, Commerce and Industrial Relations
Group - 23 June 1997
Contents
Major Issues Summary
Introduction
Summary of Part One: Forces for Change
Chapter One: Changing Customer Needs
Chapter Two: Technology Driven Innovation
Chapter Three: Regulation as a Driver of Change
Chapter Four: The Changing Financial Landscape
Summary of Part Two: Key Issues in Regulatory Reform
Chapter Five: Philosophy of Financial Regulation
Chapter Six: Cost and Efficiency
Chapter Seven: Conduct and Disclosure
Chapter Eight: Financial Safety
Chapter Nine: Stability and Payments
Chapter Ten: Mergers and Acquisitions
Chapter Eleven: Promoting Increased Efficiency
Chapter Twelve: Coordination and Accountability
Chapter Thirteen: Managing Change
Summary of Part Three: Stocktake of Financial Deregulation
Chapter Fourteen: Stocktake, Historical Perspective
Chapter Fifteen: Stocktake, The Financial System
Chapter Sixteen: Stocktake, Financial Regulation
Chapter Seventeen: Stocktake, The Economy
Critique of the Report: Some Opposing Policy Arguments
Consumer Protection
The Mega Prudential Regulator
Separating Prudential Regulation from the RBA
Fees and Charges
Access Points to Financial Institutions
The Six Pillars Policy
Foreign Ownership
Deposit Insurance
Appendix: Recommendations of the Wallis Report
Conduct and Disclosure
Financial Safety
Stability and Payments
Mergers and Acquisitions
Promoting Increased Efficiency
Coordination and Accountability
Managing Change
Abbreviations
-
ACCC
-
Australian Competition and Consumer Commission
-
AFIC
-
Australian Financial Institutions Commission
-
APRC
-
Australian Prudential Regulation Commission
-
APSC
-
Australian Payments System Council
-
ASC
-
Australian Securities Commission
-
ATM
-
Automatic Teller Machine
-
BBP
- Basic
Banking Product
-
CFSC
-
Corporations and Financial Services Commission
-
DTI
-
Deposit Taking Institution
-
EFTPOS
-
Electronic Funds Transfer/Point of Sale
-
ESA
-
Exchange Settlement Account
-
ISC
-
Insurance and Superannuation Commission
-
NBFI
- Non
Bank Financial Institution
-
OTC
- Over
the Counter
-
PSB
-
Payments System Board
-
RBA
-
Reserve Bank of Australia
-
RTGS
- Real
Time Gross Settlement
-
SME
- Small
and Medium Enterprise
The Wallis Report has proposed that some fundamental changes be made to
financial regulatory arrangements in order to increase the efficiency and
effectiveness of the system and build upon the existing achievements of
financial deregulation. The Australian financial system is experiencing ongoing
change in response to changing customer needs, new technology and other economic
policy reforms. It is argued that financial regulatory reform will allow the
financial sector to better respond to these pressures.
It is recommended that a Corporations
and Financial Services Commission (CFSC) be formed to provide Commonwealth
regulation of corporations, financial market integrity and financial consumer
protection. The current
regulatory structure in these areas is argued to be inconsistent with the
broadening direction of markets, has resulted in inefficiencies, inconsistencies
and regulatory gaps, and is not conducive to competition in the financial
system. The new structure will help to overcome these problems.
The Australian Securities Commission (ASC)
would be abolished and its current functions folded into the CFSC, while the
administration of financial consumer protection would be taken away from the
Australian Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC) and placed with the CFSC.
Some functions of the Insurance and Superannuation Commission (ISC) would also
be incorporated into the CFSC. The CFSC should have powers provided by
legislation which are commensurate with its responsibilities.
It is also recommended that a single
prudential regulator, the Australian Prudential Regulation Commission (APRC),
be formed for the entire financial system to provide integrated and consistent
supervision of financial institutions for safety purposes. A
single prudential regulator offers regulatory neutrality, greater efficiency and
responsiveness, greater resource flexibility, economies of scale and lower costs
in regulation, and more flexibility to cope with likely future changes in the
financial system.
Bank supervision would be taken away from the Reserve Bank of Australia (RBA)
and given to the APRC, while the supervision of building societies and credit
unions, now done by the state-based Australian Financial Institutions Commission
(AFIC), would also be incorporated into APRC, as would the remaining functions
of the ISC. However, the APRC would have a close cooperative relationship with
the RBA, with RBA officers having places on the APRC Board. The APRC should have
powers provided by legislation which are commensurate with its responsibilities.
In regard to the failure of financial institutions, it is recommended that the
depositor protection mechanism which currently applies to banks be extended to
all deposit taking institutions under APRC regulation. Here, depositors have
priority over other stakeholders in the disposition of remaining assets of the
institution after liquidation. Explicit deposit insurance schemes do not seem to
be practicable or workable. Existing forms of prudential regulation, such as
capital and liquidity requirements, should continue to operate.
It is proposed that the Trade Practices Act continue to apply to the financial
system and that the ACCC be the sole competition policy arbiter on mergers and
acquisitions in the sector. The current 'six pillars' policy, prohibiting
mergers between the four largest banks and two largest life offices, should be
abolished and such decisions left in the hands of the ACCC. It is not possible
to say much of any value about merger proposals in the abstract and each
requires its own particular examination.
It is recommended that the blanket prohibition on foreign takeovers of the four
largest banks be lifted and that proposed foreign investments in the financial
system be reviewed in terms of the general guidelines of the Government's direct
foreign investment policy. While large scale transfer of ownership of the
financial system into foreign hands would be contrary to the national interest,
because it would restrict options about the future development of the financial
system, it is argued that some increase in foreign ownership could bring
benefits such as injections of new capital, access to new skills and
technologies and enhanced competitive pressures in domestic financial markets.
It is argued that the widespread existence of cross-subsidies between products,
channels and customer groups reduces efficiency in the financial system by
creating divergences between costs and prices. Such cross-subsidies can be
unwound by allowing institutions full freedom to set fees and charges on their
services and products according to cost-relevant criteria. It is therefore
argued that governments should not intervene in, or otherwise try to influence,
this process. Other ways should be sought, such as through the tax/ transfer
payments system, to provide low cost transaction services to groups such as
social security recipients.
Financial regulatory agencies should have operational autonomy to pursues their
legislated objectives in the most efficient and cost effective manner possible.
They should finance their operational costs through levies upon the institutions
they supervise.
It is proposed that a Financial Sector Advisory Council be formed to advise on
regulatory arrangements and other matters, while the RBA, APRC and CFSC should
constitute a renamed Council of Financial Regulators to facilitate cooperation
across the full range of regulatory matters. It is argued that further
amalgamation of these three agencies would be unnecessary and counterproductive
at this time.
Many of the Report's recommendations can be, and have been, challenged. First,
the proposed formation of the CFSC might be challenged on the grounds that it
entails removing the administration of financial consumer protection from the
ACCC. It could be argued that this policy change will create disparities in
consumer protection with the rest of the economy, because of the tendency for
the industry-specific CFSC to come under 'undue' influence from the finance
sector. If this occurred it could be viewed as both unfair and likely to
generate some loss of economic efficiency.
Second, it could be argued that the formation of a single prudential regulator
for the entire financial sector, the APRC, will reduce the effectiveness and
efficiency of prudential regulation. It is argued that this will arise because
of the size and complexity of the regulatory task set for the APRC. The proposed
single prudential regulator might also be criticised on the grounds that it will
encourage non-deposit institutions, and their customers, to increase their risk
exposures in the belief, albeit mistaken, that Commonwealth Government
protection for bank deposits has been extended to other financial assets.
Third, separating prudential regulation from the RBA might be challenged on the
grounds that it might dangerously slow down the provision of emergency loan
assistance to institutions in times of distress, since such assistance would,
under the Report's proposals, require mutual agreement and coordination between
the APRC and the RBA. Separation might also be criticised for closing off the
option of the coordinated deployment of monetary policy and prudential policy
instruments.
Fourth, it could be argued that the Report's advocacy of more efficient pricing
of fees and charges by financial institutions clashes with equity concerns about
the rights of citizens to the provision of 'basic banking services', especially
for low-income, low-wealth customers. If compensation through the tax/ transfer
payment system is not implemented, then legislation to ensure the continued
provision of such services might be argued to be warranted. Similarly, it could
be argued that the community has rights of access to financial institutions
which should constrain the ongoing rationalisation of the distribution channels
of financial institutions. Thus, it could be argued that the Commonwealth
Government should ensure that the geographical coverage and range of type of
access does not fall below some minimum limits.
Fifth, it could be argued that the issue of mergers between the four largest
banks is of such national importance that it justifies the continuation of
explicit Commonwealth restrictions in this area. The Commonwealth Government has
already announced such a position.
Sixth, the Report's rather ambivalent attitude towards direct foreign investment
in the finance sector might be criticised on the grounds that it sits very oddly
with concerns with increasing financial sector efficiency and does not
explicitly deal with current issues such as the role of foreign bank branches in
Australia. As an alternative, it could be argued that one strength of explicit
deposit insurance schemes is that they facilitate a better role for such branch
operations. Well-designed deposit insurance schemes might also generate
efficiency, equity and safety gains in the finance sector. It could be argued
that these issues were not adequately discussed in the Report.
Australia has a long history of conducting public inquiries into its financial
system. The Campbell Committee reported in 1981 and advocated substantial
financial deregulation.(1) Their Report's conclusions were largely validated by
the Martin Review Report of 1983.(2) Financial deregulation, and its impact on
banking, was reviewed by the House of Representatives Standing Committee on
Finance and Public Administration (the Martin Committee) in 1991.(3) In the same
year, the Industry Commission examined the financial system in terms of the
availability of capital for investment.(4) Now, the Wallis Committee has
published its own review of financial deregulation and of ways to build upon
past achievements through further regulatory reform.(5)
This paper provides a concise summary of the arguments and recommendations of
the Wallis Report using, wherever possible, the actual language and sentences of
the Report. All 115 recommendations of the Report are mentioned and each of its
chapters is summarised individually. In order to fully and fairly cover the
debate on the policy changes advocated by the Report, the paper concludes with a
survey of arguments opposing some of the key conclusions and recommendations of
the Report.
Chapter One: Changing Customer Needs
Changing customer needs are helping to reshape the financial system by
influencing choices on distribution channels, financial products and financial
suppliers. In turn, such needs have been primarily influenced by changes in
demographic structure, work patterns, the financial assets and liabilities of
households, awareness of value and willingness to adopt new technology.
The Australian population is ageing. This increases the importance of assets to
fund consumption in retirement. The Commonwealth Government has sought, through
superannuation initiatives, to encourage private asset accumulation and thus to
encourage reduced dependence upon the age pension in retirement. This has led to
a shift in household financial assets into market-linked investments, meaning
that households are bearing more investment risk than in the past. Improved
financial advisory services and increased efficiency in funds management are
thus required.
The number of people working extended hours continues to increase. Thus, many
people may now have less leisure time and less time available to manage their
financial affairs. Such people will have a greater need for financial products
which offer convenience and ease of access. At the same time, many consumers
will experience greater variability in the timing of income. Those spending
longer periods in education, those in part-time employment, the unemployed and
those in early retirement will generate a greater need for financial products
which smooth cash flows and spending over their life cycles.
Households continue to accumulate both assets and liabilities. Thus, households
now rely more on the financial system and have greater exposure to financial
institutions. They will be more concerned with issues of financial efficiency
and safety. Those with greater net financial wealth will tend to shift their
assets towards more risky, higher return products such as holdings of
market-linked investments. Consumers are becoming increasingly aware of value
for money in financial products and services. Information sources on the
financial system have proliferated. Rising fees and charges on transactions
services have increased customer value awareness. The rising range of housing
loan products has encouraged consumers to shop around for the best deal. There
is also an increased willingness to take up new technologies providing financial
services. This is related to increased familiarity with the new technologies in
the workplace and in the home.
Chapter Two: Technology Driven Innovation
Improvements in communications infrastructure and technology are breaking down
physical constraints and cost barriers to the transmission, storage and use of
information. Information networks are expanding rapidly. Pressures for
standardisation, interoperability, ease of use and cost effectiveness are
increasing. Enhanced authentication of users and more secure transmission of
information will accelerate network use.
Electronic channels for payments and financial service delivery are increasingly
taking advantage of networks. The expansion of Automatic Teller Machines (ATMs)
and Electronic Funds Transfer/ Point of Sale (EFTPOS) access points have
generated a large shift towards electronic retail transactions and away from
reliance upon access to the branches of financial institutions. Telephone
banking is also encouraging such trends. Once security is improved, the conduct
of financial transactions through the Internet will expand rapidly. Operating
costs per transaction are much lower through these new electronic mediums.
Figure 1: Percentage of Transactions using Specific
Financial Channels in September 1996
Note: Base = Volume of Transactions/visits, September 1996.
Source: Data provided to the Wallis Inquiry by Roy Morgan Research.
Risk assessment relating to financial products has become much more
sophisticated through advanced data analysis capabilities made possible by
technological advances. Technology has profoundly influenced the conduct of
financial markets and exchanges. Organised markets and exchanges are facing
competition from the availability of information and trading systems which
threaten the value of their business. Organisations standing between the
customer and the ultimate supplier of financial services must increasingly
justify their value in the delivery process.
Chapter Three: Regulation as a Driver of Change
Changes in regulation have strongly affected the financial sector. The four most
important policy changes have been the liberalisation of trade and capital
flows, the development of compulsory superannuation, the removal of direct
government participation in the financial services industry, and changes to
taxation.
Economic globalisation is proceeding apace. Markets are becoming more
internationally integrated and the economies of different nations are becoming
more interdependent. These trends have been partly due to technological advances
and broadening planning horizons of firms and investors. They have been also
much assisted in the case of Australia by policy relaxations such as the lifting
of restrictions on outward investment by Australian companies, the floating of
the Australian dollar and the abolition of exchange controls, the liberalisation
of restrictions on inward direct foreign investment, and the progressive opening
of the Australian banking system to foreign banks.
The development of compulsory superannuation contributions has led to the rapid
growth in aggregate assets in superannuation funds. The great bulk of these have
been invested in more risky market-linked assets rather than in capital
guaranteed assets on the balance sheets of financial intermediaries.
In recent years the Commonwealth and State governments have corporatised and
then privatised many of their financial enterprises. This has been motivated by
the desire of governments to exit commercial businesses (including non-financial
enterprises) to ensure that competitive neutrality is achieved in those markets,
and has also been prompted by losses in certain state-government-owned
businesses and the resultant burden on their taxpayers.
Taxation arrangements in Australia, like those in many other countries, contain
a wide range of economic distortions. Taxation has been a key factor in the
creation of legal and organisational structures specifically designed to
minimise taxation liability. Progress has been made in reducing distortions in
some areas but many remain. Variations in effective taxation rates across assets
and saving vehicles remain substantial, while the rates and scope of transaction
taxes also distort financial flows.
Chapter Four: The Changing Financial Landscape
The financial system has undergone, and will continue to undergo, four central
types of structural change. There is an increased focus upon efficiency and
competition, globalisation of financial markets is continuing, financial market
widening and the development of financial 'conglomerates' has arisen, and there
has been a further shift from financial institutions to direct connections
between capital suppliers and final users, through financial markets.
Financial institutions have improved their ability to identify costs and profits
entailed in the products and services they offer. The use of customer and
product profitability models allows institutions to price products and services
more accurately. As these methods come to be more widely used, they will combine
with enhanced competition to generate pricing which more accurately reflects the
underlying cost of supply, thus raising the economic efficiency of the financial
sector. Specialist financial providers have overcome barriers to entry in the
most profitable financial markets and have thus intensified competition in these
areas. Such intensified competition has increased pressure to abandon
inefficient pricing in other financial services which have been traditionally
used to 'cross-subsidise' other products. More efficient pricing will encourage
consumers to use lower-cost channels of access to products and services, thus
reinforcing the trend to greater efficiency in the financial system.
Australian markets have become increasingly global over the last decade and now
have a relatively high level of integration with international markets.
Australian businesses and markets have responded in four ways. Fundraising by
corporations and institutions is becoming increasingly global. Foreign inward
and outward investment are both growing. Trading on share, bond and foreign
exchange markets is becoming increasingly more international. The location
decisions of many financial services corporations reflect an increasingly
international perspective. However, at this stage the globalisation of retail
financial services is still relatively undeveloped.
Increased globalisation intensifies competition for domestic financial
suppliers, increases pressures for rationalisation and international
harmonisation of financial regulation in Australia, and heightens the exposure
of Australia to world financial trends and shocks.
The Australian financial system is already predominantly composed of financial
conglomerates. These are groups of companies under common control whose
predominant activities consist of providing at least two different classes of
financial services. For example, many Australian banks have operations in funds
management and insurance. Underlying trends are resulting in conglomerates which
focus on a wider spectrum of activities. Heightened competition is encouraging a
reconfiguration of conglomerates to achieve more cost efficient structures.
Conglomeration is also assisted by product innovation where products are
designed to be offered by a range of financial entities, and by commercial
strategies of 'bundling' of financial products across traditional market
boundaries.
Financial markets are increasingly challenging financial intermediaries for the
provision of finance and the management of risk. Large corporations have had
direct access to financial markets, for debt and equity fundraising, for some
time. Developments in 'securitisation' (the bundling of loan assets and their
sale as marketable securities) now allow markets to provide finance to retail
borrowers. An increasing range of risks can be managed through an array of
market-based 'derivative' financial instruments (e.g. options, swaps and futures
contracts), while the needs of savers are also increasingly being met through
financial market products. Financial intermediaries will continue to perform an
important role in meeting the financial needs of their clients but the form of
their participation is likely to change.
Chapter Five: Philosophy of Financial Regulation
Regulation of all markets for goods and services can be categorised according to
three broad purposes. First, regulation is to help ensure that markets work
efficiently and competitively, and thus to overcome sources of market failure.
Second, regulation can prescribe particular standards or qualities of service,
especially where the consumption of goods and services carries risks, so that
safety is a focus of concern. Third, regulation can help achieve social
objectives such as, for example, 'community service obligations' which typically
take the form of price controls.
More particularly, general financial system regulation can be motivated by four
considerations. Financial market integrity regulation aims to promote confidence
in the efficiency and fairness of markets. Financial market prices can be
sensitive to information and this raises the potential for misuse of
information. For this reason regulators impose specific disclosure rules (such
as prospectus rules) and conduct rules (such as prohibitions on insider trading)
on financial market participants. Consumer financial protection arises from the
complexity of financial products and the consequent scope for deception,
misunderstanding and dispute. Competition regulation of financial markets arises
from concerns over the anti-competitive effects of market concentration and
collusion between financial market participants.
A case for regulation also arises from the risks attached to financial promises
(such as the promise to repay borrowed funds). As a general principle, financial
regulation for safety purposes will be required where promises are judged to be
very difficult to honour, difficult to assess, and likely to produce highly
adverse consequence if breached. Financial promises which rank high on all three
characteristics (e.g. promises to repay retail deposits) are called 'high
intensity' promises.
In markets for intense financial promises, two sources of market failure have
long been recognised. First, there is the risk of third party losses due to
systemic instability. The most potent source of the risk of systemic instability
is financial contagion, where financial distress in one market or institution is
communicated to others and eventually engulfs the entire system through a
general loss of confidence. Second, there is the problem of information
asymmetry facing most consumers, which means that they cannot reliably assess
risk, particularly the creditworthiness of the financial promisor.
Financial regulation for safety purposes is called 'prudential regulation' and
is intended to prevent the emergence of problems which threaten the viability of
financial institutions. Once such problems have emerged, the task falls to the
central bank and government to restore stability through the provision of
liquidity and other policies.
Overall, it should be noted that there are five broad principles of good
financial regulation. First, competitive neutrality requires that regulation
apply equally and to all who make particular financial commitments. It further
requires that there be minimal barriers to entry and exit from markets and
products, that there be no undue restrictions on institutions or the products
they offer, and that markets be open to the widest possible range of
participants.
Second, cost effectiveness requires that regulation be no more onerous than
necessary to achieve its goals, minimise overlap and duplication and conflict
amongst regulators, properly balance efficiency and effectiveness, distinguish
the goals of financial regulation from broader social objectives, and allocate
regulatory costs to those enjoying its benefits.
Third, transparency of regulation requires that all government guarantees be
made explicit and that all purchasers and providers of financial services be
fully aware of their rights and responsibilities. Fourth, flexibility requires
that the regulatory framework must be able to adapt and cope with changing
institutional and product structures without losing effectiveness. Fifth,
accountability requires that regulatory agencies operate independently of
sectional interests, be subject to regular reviews and evaluations and be open
to scrutiny by their stakeholders.
Chapter Six: Cost and Efficiency
It is estimated that in 1995 the total cost to users of the Australian financial
system was about $41 billion. This is more than the residential construction
sector or the costs of the entire retail sector. Banks made up about $22 billion
of these financial system costs.
In general, significant improvements should be able to be achieved through the
removal of inefficient regulation and the enhancement of competition in
financial markets; these required reforms are discussed in later chapters.
In regard to the banking system, where potential improvements are estimated to
be large, most of the efficiency and cost reduction gains can be achieved by
changing the mix of transaction channels in favour of electronic transactions,
by reducing the density of the branch network and by using more differentiated
branch formats (e.g. kiosks versus full branches).
Figure 2: Bank Branch Density
Note: The range of included institutions may vary slightly due to national
differences in classification. Figures for Australia include banks and building
societies.
Source: Bank of International Settlements, 1996, 66th
Annual Report; KPMG 1996, New Zealand Financial Institutions Performance Survey.
In regard to insurance, where potential improvements are estimated to be of
medium magnitude, while there is scope to improve the cost structures of
individual insurance companies, this is best achieved through competition rather
than through regulation. In regard to the funds management industry, where
potential improvements are estimated to be large, regulation and taxation rules
have contributed to its high cost levels by creating barriers to foreign entry
and by failing to encourage the consolidation of the fragmented superannuation
industry. Further unnecessary cost is added by the lack of low-cost distribution
channels.
The costs of the payments system, where potential improvements are also
estimated to be large, are driven directly by the frequency of use of different
instruments and by the proportion of electronic transactions. Despite the rapid
uptake of some forms of electronic payments instruments such as EFTPOS,
Australia still depends heavily on cheques. As a result, total payments system
costs are relatively high by international standards, constituting between $5
billion and $7.5 billion annually.
Figure 3: Automatic Teller Machine (ATM) and EFTPOS Penetration
(1995)
Note: Not all systems have the same functionality (e.g. on-line capabilities) as
those in Australia.
Source: Bank of International Settlements, 1996, Statistics
on the Payments Systems in the Group of Ten Countries, RBA and APCA
(unpublished data).
Chapter Seven: Conduct and Disclosure
Financial markets cannot work well unless participants act with integrity, to
ensure mutual trust, and unless there is adequate disclosure to facilitate
informed judgements. Regulation is necessary to ensure that these conditions
hold. Market integrity regulation seeks to ensure that markets are sound,
orderly and transparent, users are treated fairly, the price formation process
is reliable and markets are free from misleading, manipulative or abusive
conduct. Consumer protection regulation seeks to ensure that retail customers
have adequate information, are treated fairly and have adequate avenues for
redress.
Such conduct and disclosure regulation is currently undertaken by several
Commonwealth agencies, such as the Insurance and Superannuation Commission (ISC),
the Australian Securities Commission (ASC), the Australian Competition and
Consumer Commission (ACCC), and the Australian Payments System Council (APSC).
Most such regulation is based on the institutional form of the service provider,
although market integrity regulation is conducted on a functional basis by one
agency alone, the ASC. This regulatory structure is inconsistent with the
broadening structure of markets, has resulted in inefficiencies, inconsistencies
and regulatory gaps, and is not conducive to competition in the financial
system.
In order to overcome these problems, it is recommended that a single agency, the
Corporations and Financial Services Commission (CFSC), should be established to
provide Commonwealth regulation of corporations, financial market integrity and
financial consumer protection. It should combine the existing market integrity,
corporations and consumer protection roles of the ASC, ISC and APSC. The tasks
of these three roles are more complementary than conflicting. The CFSC should
take over the administration of consumer protection in the financial system from
the ACCC, and especially monitor the use of new technology in relation to
consumer protection. On the other hand, the States and Territories should retain
and review their consumer credit laws.
The CFSC should have powers to use a combination of regulatory approaches. In
addition to its framework legislation, the CFSC should have the power to adopt
detailed codes which prescribe appropriate conduct and disclosure in particular
industries or to allow the industry to develop such codes. Given these broad
powers, the CFSC should have the discretion to decide the best approach to
regulation to be used in particular circumstances. The CFSC should have an
explicit mandate to balance the efficiency and effectiveness of its regulatory
approaches.
It is recommended that a number of specific current regulatory practices also be
reformed. Disclosure requirements for retail financial products should be
reviewed by the CFSC to ensure that they provide information that enables
comparison between products. The disclosure codes of conduct applying to
banking, building societies and credit unions should be made consistent wherever
possible, while 'due diligence' defences should apply to positive disclosure
requirements. As well, the law should be amended to require the issue of
succinct profile statements about offers of retail financial products, including
initial public offers. In order to avoid information overload for consumers, the
CFSC should encourage shorter prospectuses where applicable. Financial
institutions' financial reports should meet both Corporations
Law and prudential supervision
requirements, while the accounting standards of financial institutions should be
harmonised with international standards.
The CFSC should establish a single regime to license advisers providing
investment advice and dealing in financial markets. There should be separate
categories of licence for investment advice and product sales, general insurance
brokers, financial market dealers, and financial market participants. However,
the CFSC should have power to delegate accreditation responsibilities to
industry bodies.
On the other hand, the CFSC should develop a single set of requirements for
investment sales and advice concerning minimum standards of competency and
ethical behaviour, the disclosure of fees and adviser's capacity, rules on
handling client property and money, financial resources or insurance available
in cases of fraud or incompetence, and responsibilities for agents and
employees. In particular, real estate agents providing investment advice should
be required to hold a financial advisory licence unless a review clearly
indicates otherwise. However, professional advisers, such as accountants and
lawyers, should not be required to hold a financial advisory licence if they
provide investment advice only incidentally to their other business and rebate
any commissions to clients. Additional prudential regulation of financial market
licence holders is not required at this time.
Broader regulation of 'financial products' should replace current, less
flexible, securities and futures law. The CFSC should authorise financial
exchanges (such as the Stock Exchange and the Futures Exchange) under a single
regime, while the ACCC and the CFSC should coordinate their examination of
exchange rules. The regulation of exchanges should not be excessive compared
with Over-the-Counter (OTC) markets which involve more specialised transactions
between buyers and sellers. In particular, prohibitions on retail participation
in OTC derivative markets should be discontinued. OTC markets may be conducted
by appropriately licensed financial market dealers, while exchange clearing
houses should be appropriately authorised. A central national gateway for
dispute resolution for all consumers of retail financial services and products
should be established.
Overall, the CFSC should have broad enforcement powers and resources which are
adequate for carrying out its responsibilities. In particular, it should have
adequate powers over investigations, protection from liability for those
providing regulatory assistance, the imposition of administrative sanctions such
as disqualification and banning orders, the initiation of civil actions in the
courts, and the referral of matters to the Director of Public Prosecutions for
criminal prosecution. The CFSC should also participate in global regulatory
programs to provide consumer protection for cross-border financial transactions.
Chapter Eight: Financial Safety
Financial safety is fundamental to the smooth operation of the economic system.
Government intervention through prudential regulation provides an added level of
financial safety beyond that provided by conduct and disclosure regulation. The
intensity of prudential regulation should be proportional to the degree of
market failure it addresses, but it should not involve a government guarantee of
any part of the financial system.
The current framework for prudential regulation is institutionally based, with
separate agencies regulating the activities of each class of institution. The
Reserve Bank Australia (RBA) covers banks and the payments settlement, the ISC
covers life and general insurance and superannuation, while the state-based
Financial Institutions Scheme, coordinated by the Australian Financial
Institutions Commission (AFIC) covers credit unions, building societies and, it
is expected, friendly societies from 1 July, 1997.
Prudential regulation should be imposed on institutions licensed to conduct the
general business of deposit taking from the public, or offering capital backed
life products, general insurance products or superannuation investments. A
single Commonwealth agency, the Australian Prudential Regulation Commission (APRC),
should be established to carry out regulation for all these products. That is,
it should conduct prudential regulation throughout the financial system. The
APRC should be separate from, but cooperate closely with, the RBA.
A single prudential regulator offers regulatory neutrality and greater
efficiency and responsiveness, provides a sounder basis for regulating
conglomerates, offers the prospect of greater resource flexibility and economies
of scale in regulation that should enhance the cost effectiveness of regulation,
and provides the flexibility and breadth of vision to cope with changes that
seem likely to occur in the financial system in the coming years.
Separating the prudential regulator from the RBA recognises the supervision
functions for non-bank institutions which the regulator will be taking on,
clarifies the nature of the assurance provided by prudential regulation to
customers of financial institutions, and enables each organisation to focus
clearly on its primary responsibilities and clarifies the lines of
accountability for their regulatory tasks. It also removes a potential conflict
of interest for the regulator in cases where institutions require emergency
liquidity assistance and the prudential regulator might be too willing to
provide it in order to bolster its own reputation for preventing institutional
failure. Allowing this function to remain with the RBA, as is recommended,
avoids this problem.
However, the RBA should have three ex-officio members on the APRC Board, and
provision should also be made for full information exchange between the RBA and
the APRC and for RBA participation in APRC teams inspecting financial
institutions. The RBA should retain responsibility for reporting under the Financial
Institutions Act 1974. A bilateral operational coordination committee
should be established between the RBA and the APRC. The three financial system
regulators-the RBA, CFSC and APRC- should also continue to pursue operational
cooperation through a joint council chaired by the RBA. This is discussed in a
later chapter.
The APRC should be empowered under legislation to enforce prudential regulations
on any licensed or approved financial entity. Unlicensed entities would be
prohibited from offering financial products for which approval had not been
given. Licenses could be revoked or made conditional on certain courses of
action. However, the intensity of prudential regulation needs to balance
financial safety with consideration of its possible adverse effects upon
efficiency, competition, innovation and competitive neutrality. This balance
should preserve a spectrum of market risk-and-return choices for retail
investors, thus meeting their differing needs and preferences.
Prudential regulation of all licensed Deposit-Taking Institutions (DTIs) should
be consistent with standards approved by the Basle Committee of Banking
Supervision and should aim to ensure that the risk of loss of depositors' funds
is remote. Quantitative prudential requirements such as capital adequacy,
liquidity requirements and large exposure limits should apply. Regular on-site
reviews of risk management systems should form an integral part of the approach
to prudential regulation.
The APRC should be responsible for the licensing of all DTIs subject to
prudential regulation. Only those entities which meet minimum capital
requirements and hold an exchange settlement account (ESA) with the RBA should
be entitled to use the name 'bank', while only those entities which are mutually
owned (where each depositor has an equal share of ownership) should be entitled
to use the names 'credit union', 'credit society' or 'mutual'. Any licensed DTI
should be entitled to use the name 'building society' and licensed DTIs should
be entitled to use any other business names provided they are not, in the view
of the APRC, misleading to depositors. Deposit taking by unlicensed entities
(such as finance companies) should be subject to the fundraising provisions of
the Corporations
Law and be regulated by the CFSC.
The APRC should regulate life companies and general insurers, while the
regulation of friendly societies should be shared between the CFSC and the APRC.
The APRC should regulate superannuation in accordance with retirement
objectives, while other APRC regulated institutions should have the right to
offer Retirement Savings Accounts (RSAs). However, 'excluded' superannuation
funds (with less than 5 members) should be exempt from APRC regulation. Overall,
the APRC should promote transparent disclosure of institutional activities and
performance in order to strengthen risk assessment by customers and
shareholders.
The general principle of a wide spread of ownership of regulated financial
entities (or holding companies where part of a conglomerate) should be retained.
This protects against undue influence by a major shareholder and also guards
against contagion risk that may otherwise occur if a financial institution is
damaged by adverse changes in the fortunes of its major shareholder. Existing
legislation and rules should be streamlined through the introduction of a single Acquisitions
Act with a common 15%
shareholding limit. The APRC should have power to approve, subject to prudential
requirements, an exemption allowing an existing licence holder to acquire more
than 15% of an institution. Any other person may acquire more than 15% of a
licensed institution only if the Treasurer approves the acquisition in the
national interest.
Current policy generally requires the separation of the ownership of DTIs and
life companies from other sectors of the economy. This is justified principally
on the basis of the need to ensure that the safety of the financial sector is
not compromised by the influence or fortunes of other entities. The general
principle of separation of regulated financial activities from other activities
should be retained but applied with greater flexibility than at present. Mutual
entities should be permitted to hold all classes of licences. New applicants for
licences are currently required to meet certain capital requirements. In
general, these should be retained but the APRC should be flexible in granting
exemptions under some circumstances.
Financial conglomerates raise the issue of the most appropriate legal structure
in which they should operate. It is recommended that, subject to a financial
conglomerate meeting prudential requirements, the APRC should permit adoption of
a non-operating holding company structure. The structure must satisfy the APRC
in the areas of capital management, adequacy of firewalls, reporting of
intra-group activities and independent board representation on subsidiary
entities. A conglomerate should not be prohibited from obtaining a number of
classes of licences or conducting non-regulated financial activities. The APRC
should have clear powers to verify intra-group exposures and otherwise satisfy
itself as to the adequacy of the separation of the regulated financial entity
from other financial operations of the group.
Turning to some other financial entities, fundraising by money market
corporations and finance companies should be subject to CFSC surveillance but
not APRC regulation.
Finally, in regard to dealing with the failure of financial institutions, the
depositor protection mechanism that currently applies to banks should, subject
to appropriate transitional arrangements, be extended to all regulated DTIs.
Associated resolution arrangements should be transferred to the APRC and
clarified by legislative amendment. Current depositor protection provisions
would provide a greater level of security, in the event of collapse and
liquidation, than an explicit deposit insurance scheme and are to be preferred
on these grounds.
To facilitate depositor protection, restrictions on the classes of debt and
equity that may be issued by DTIs, particularly mutual institutions, should, as
far as possible, be removed (in order to expand non-deposit sources of funds).
In regard to insurance companies and superannuation funds, the APRC should be
empowered to replace management or trustee control of regulated financial
entities in the event of their actual or likely failure. Existing policy holder
preferences applied to statutory funds of life companies should be retained and
extended to benefit funds of friendly societies.
Chapter Nine: Stability and Payments
In any financial system a limited range of financial claims can be used as a
means of payment to settle transactions. For example, notes and coins, the
deposit liabilities of banks (mobilised by instruments such as cheques) and
credit cards backed by lines of credit, can all be used to settle transactions,
and thus form part of the payments system.
There is scope for increased competition in the payments system which will help
to lower its costs of operation. However, this must be balanced against
the need to maintain stability in the financial system.
The payments system provides one central
way in which instability can be generated. The RBA should retain overall
responsibility for the stability of the financial system, the provision of
emergency liquidity assistance and for regulating the payments system.
Large scale instability (called systemic instability) can arise from default on
settlement of transactions, especially for high value transactions on bonds,
foreign exchange and derivatives products where receipts and payments may not be
synchronised. Initiatives such as the 'real-time-gross-settlement' (RTGS) system
should mitigate domestic sources of settlement risk; here, each high value
transaction is settled as it occurs. Time lags in other settlements are also
being shortened. However, substantial risks remain, especially for international
transactions. The RBA should give high priority to promoting further
cost-effective control of both domestic and international settlement risks. On
the other hand, the CFSC should be responsible for regulation of financial
exchanges in these matters.
Apart from settlement risk, financial system instability may also have its
origins in generalised disruption to financial and other markets. Confidence in
some financial market participants may plummet and this may generate a broader
market crisis. The policy responses to such developments will vary with their
particular circumstances but may include the provisions of emergency funds (i.e.
liquidity) to markets generally or to particular sectors. These should remain
the responsibility of the RBA (in consultation with the Treasurer), in its role
as both monetary authority and manager of systemic risk.
Increased competition in the payments system is possible without jeopardising
systemic stability. A new institutional framework is necessary to achieve this.
Existing arrangements should be dissolved and a new Payments System Board (PSB)
should be formed within the RBA to regulate payments with a view to increasing
efficiency and competition. It should set performance benchmarks for these goals
and its membership should reflect this. The RBA's regulatory activities in these
areas should be clearly separated from its commercial activities, such as acting
as main banker to governments.
In regard to specific reforms to
increase competition and efficiency, the right to issue cheques in their own
name should be extended to all licensed DTIs. The ACCC and the Payment System
Board should monitor the delivery fees charged on credit and debit cards
while the ACCC should monitor the rules of international credit card
associations to ensure they are not overly restrictive. Access to final
clearance for financial transactions should be liberalised, its efficiency
upgraded, and the Trade
Practices Act 1974 should
continue to apply to it. Access to ESAs with the RBA should be liberalised,
while non deposit-taking institutions should be able to directly settle consumer
electronic and bulk electronic payments through an ESA.
In regard to increased financial system security, RTGS benchmarks should be
established, the PSB should issue payments system approvals and the PSB and the
APRC should establish close coordination arrangements, while holders of 'stores
of value' for payments instruments such as traveller's cheques and smart cards
should be subject to prudential regulation. High-value settlement providers
should be regulated to international standards.
Chapter Ten: Mergers and Acquisitions
A competitive financial system is in the best interests of Australia and the
laws and administration of policies on mergers and acquisitions play an
important role in achieving this. The Trade
Practices Act 1974 provides a
set of economy-wide laws on competition. It is recommended that Section 50 of
the Act should continue to apply to the financial system, so that a merger is
prohibited where, in a substantial market, a substantial lessening of
competition would be likely to result. Indeed, theTrade
Practices Act should provide the
only competition regulation of financial system mergers. The ACCC should
continue to administer competition laws for the financial system. However, the
APRC (and not the Treasurer) should be given powers to regulate mergers and
acquisitions on prudential grounds.
In particular, the current 'six pillars' policy should be abolished. Under this
policy, mergers are not permitted between the four largest banks (National
Australia, Commonwealth, ANZ and Westpac) and the two largest life insurance
institutions (AMP and National Mutual). There are no persuasive arguments for
continuing to separate out such possible mergers from the general operation of
competition policy and then to impose a blanket ban upon them.
On the other hand, this Report makes no recommendations about particular merger
scenarios and it is not possible to comment definitively on assessment criteria
in the abstract. However, the methodologies used in recent ACCC examinations of
proposed bank mergers need review. Competition in retail transaction accounts
and small business finance, currently at relatively low levels, is likely to be
crucial in future assessments of merger proposals. The ongoing formation of
national markets in some banking products and the competitive effects of the
presence of regional banks will also be important considerations. In general,
assessments of merger proposals should always take account of changes occurring
in that sector.
In regard to foreign investment, the current policy position prohibiting the
foreign takeover of any of the four major banks should be explicitly removed and
replaced with a policy which provides that all foreign acquisitions in the
financial system will be assessed through the general provisions of foreign
investment policy under the Foreign
Acquisitions and Takeovers Act 1975. While a large scale transfer of
ownership of the financial system to foreign hands would be contrary to the
national interest (since it would restrict options for the future development of
the financial system), some increase in foreign ownership of aspects of the
Australian financial system could generate significant benefits such as
injections of new capital, access to new skills and technologies and enhanced
competitive pressures in domestic financial markets.
Chapter Eleven: Promoting Increased Efficiency
The funds management industry is composed of funds collectively invested in life
insurance, superannuation, equities and unit trusts. It has both retail and
wholesale dimensions. Funds management fees in Australia appear to be higher
than those in comparable countries. One of the potential reasons for higher
costs in Australia is the fragmentation of the managed funds industry.
Regulatory reform can improve the performance of the managed funds industry. The
following specific reforms are recommended. Foreign investment regulations
restricting foreign owned or controlled managers of collective investments
should be reviewed. The Corporations
Law should be amended to provide
for the application of takeover provisions modelled on Chapter 6 of the Corporations
Law for public unit trusts, and
to provide for streamlined merger and reconstruction provisions for collective
investment scheme. The Australian Stock Exchange should amend Listing Rules
15.14 to permit the exercise of sanctions in trust deeds designed to provide
unit holders with the protection embodied in Chapter 6 of the Corporations
Law.
Superannuation fund members should have greater choice of fund. Employees should
be provided with choice of fund, subject to any constraints necessary to address
concerns about administrative costs and fund liquidity. Transfer costs should be
transparent and reasonable. Regulation of collective investments and public
offer superannuation should be harmonised. The States and Territories should
give urgent priority to establishing a modern, uniform, national regime for
trustee companies. There is also considerable scope for rationalising and
standardising the taxation of collective investments, although this is outside
the Report's terms of reference.
A regulatory framework which is responsive to technological innovation will also
promote increased efficiency. Relevant legislation should be generally amended
to allow for, and facilitate, electronic commerce. Regulation should not differ
between different technologies or delivery mechanisms in such a way as to favour
one technology over another. Australia should also adopt international standards
for electronic commerce, and international harmonisation of law enforcement and
consumer protection should be pursued, especially in regard to electronic
commerce. Financial regulators should keep abreast of technological developments
as they affect the financial system and liaise with each other as well as
government departments and other agencies on these issues.
The existence of cross-subsidies between products, channels and customer groups
is pervasive in the financial system. Profits from higher prices for some
transactions are used to provide prices which are lower than they would
otherwise be for other transactions. Cross-subsidies are derived from historical
product bundling, earlier difficulties with apportioning costs, and community
expectations that institutions should meet community service obligations. The
unwinding of such cross-subsidies can increase efficiency in the financial
system. Institutions should have the freedom to set fees and charges on their
services and products based upon costs, without government intervention or
suasion. Governments should expedite the examination of alternative means of
providing low-cost transaction services for remote areas and for recipients of
social security and other transfer payments.
In regard to the mortgage insurance market, which is of great importance to
mortgage lenders, the Housing Loans Insurance Corporation should be privatised
to eliminate its undercharging, in comparison to private insurers, which is
derived from the Commonwealth Government's guarantee of its activities.
Improved flows of market information can also increase efficiency. In regard to
small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs), debt markets are not seriously
deficient, while equity markets are improving. The current low investment by
superannuation fund managers in this sector will probably increase and there
should be no compulsion on funds managers to invest in SMEs. However, compared
to the United States, Australia lacks benchmarking and performance measurement
data on investment pools in the SME sector. This discourages institutional
investment there. The CFSC and the Australian Bureau of Statistics should take
into account the specific requirements of credit-rating agencies and funds
managers when reviewing SME data collection.
In regard to privacy issues, current credit reporting for lender institutions is
restricted to negative reporting of defaults and delinquencies. The Privacy
Act prevents positive credit
reporting (i.e. the successful completion of debt repayments). The latter would
be very useful in making more efficient credit assessments of potential
borrowers. This restriction should be reviewed. In a similar vein, credit
information sharing amongst group entities should be allowed unless the customer
withdraws consent. In general, reforms to the privacy regime should balance
protection, choice and efficiency, be responsive to market changes, be national
in scope, avoid duplication and deal sensibly with information collected under
previous privacy regimes. The administration of privacy laws in the financial
system should be done by the Privacy Commissioner rather than the financial
consumer protection regulator.
Chapter Twelve: Coordination and Accountability
The regulatory agencies should be established under legislation with substantial
operational autonomy. The APRC and the CFSC should establish their own staffing
and remuneration structures in whatever form will be most conducive to their
effectiveness and efficiency. They should locate their headquarters in the main
financial capitals, rather than Canberra. Inspection staff should be located in
the cities where the financial industry operates. It is only under these
conditions that regulation can be as effective and efficient as possible.
Regulatory agencies' charges should reflect their costs, subject to approval by
the Treasurer, so that they fund themselves. In this context, the current
below-market rate of interest paid by the RBA on its holdings of banks'
non-callable deposits is distortionary and should be reviewed. Regulatory
agencies should thus be 'off-budget' in their treatment by the fiscal
authorities.
APRC, CFSC and PSB should all have boards of directors responsible for their
operational and administrative policies, the fulfilment of their legislative
mandates and their performance. The key principles in the composition of these
new boards are that there should be majorities of independent members and that
there be substantial cross-representation. The chairpersons of the APRC and CFSC
boards and the PSB should be appointed by the Treasurer from among the
independent members. Each agency should report annually to Parliament and should
seek continuous improvement in reporting quality. Reports should include results
of internal assessments of efficiency, compliance costs and cost effectiveness.
Where possible, comparisons with international best-practice should be provided.
Legislation should authorise the exchange of confidential information amongst
the financial regulatory agencies.
A Financial Sector Advisory Council should be created to provide independent
advice on implementation of the new regulatory arrangements, their relevance and
cost effectiveness, the compliance costs imposed upon financial market
participants, the international competitiveness of the financial sector and new
and potential financial developments. The Council of Financial Supervisors
should be renamed as the Council of Financial Regulators and reconfigured with
the aims of facilitating the cooperation of its three members (RBA, APRC and
CFSC) across the full range of regulatory functions.
Further amalgamation of financial regulators is not warranted because it would
be premature, would reduce the benefits of specialisation and thus undermine
efficiency, and would create an agency which might be excessively powerful.
Chapter Thirteen: Managing Change
A staged approach should be adopted to implementing this Report's
recommendations, commencing with an announcement of the Government's position in
principle on the main recommendations, and followed by establishing the new
regulatory agencies and investing them with existing regulatory powers. It is
highly desirable that the Government announce its position on the mergers and
acquisitions recommendations as soon as possible, in order to quell speculation
and provide commercial certainty.
Negotiations with State and Territory Governments would also need to proceed on
the transfer of regulatory powers which are currently the responsibility of the
state-based AFIC regime. As well, a Panel for Uniform Commercial Laws should be
established to pursue uniform Commonwealth, State and Territory commercial laws.
The Panel should complete its task by no later than the end of 1999.
Chapter Fourteen: Stocktake, Historical Perspective
Tight control of the banking system in the post-World War Two era encouraged the
growth of non-bank financial institutions (NBFIs). Life companies were actively
engaged in mortgage lending to satisfy demand unmet by banks. Building societies
and credit unions also expanded. Merchant banks developed to satisfy unmet
demand for corporate borrowing. The banks themselves established subsidiary
finance companies to overcome the strict regulation of their own lending and
borrowing activities.
By the late 1970s pressure for regulatory reform was mounting through a
combination of inflation, exogenous shocks and the declining effectiveness of a
monetary policy system which was reliant upon control of banks' balance sheets,
despite the importance of NBFIs in the financial system. It was in this context
that the Campbell Committee was established in 1979; it issued its report in
1981. Its recommendations were targeted at both improving the efficiency of
macroeconomic management and at the abolition of direct interest rate and
portfolio controls on financial institutions. Although the Campbell Committee
was concerned to remove barriers to entry to the financial system, its
recommendations also included strengthened prudential measures to preserve
system stability.
As of mid-1996 the majority of the Committee's recommendations had been
implemented. Most importantly, interest rate and bank lending controls were
relaxed, barriers to entry in banking were liberalised, controls on capital
flows were abolished, and the exchange rate was floated. These policy changes
are usually called 'financial deregulation'. In the period since Campbell, many
other important policy changes have occurred, such as the privatisation of
financial institutions, the development of compulsory superannuation and
economy-wide microeconomic reform. These changes make it difficult to assess the
effects of financial deregulation.
Chapter Fifteen: Stocktake, The Financial System
The Campbell Committee believed that less intrusive regulation and greater
competition would lead to greater efficiency in the financial system, and that
consumers would benefit from these changes. However, the expected increase in
competition, particularly in the retail deposit taking sector, has been slow to
arise. Only in more recent times have some retail financial markets (e.g. home
mortgages) become obviously more competitive. On the other hand, efficiency has
improved in several areas since deregulation. Increased pricing efficiency, in
securities and foreign exchange markets in particular, has improved the
efficiency of resource allocation. The productivity of financial market
participants has also risen in many cases, with technological innovation playing
a major role in this.
International competitiveness was not a major focus of the Campbell Committee.
The limited data available provide some support for the view that underlying
competitiveness has increased since deregulation in some areas but deteriorated
in others. On the other hand, product choice has clearly widened since the early
1980s. This is attributable to deregulation as well as to technological
developments, government superannuation initiatives, and increased integration
with international financial markets. The quality of financial products has also
risen. However, one exception to the improvement of financial products and
services is the provision of information and advice, which still appears to be
in need of further development. Overall, although deregulation has yielded
benefits in the above areas, there is room for further improvement.
Chapter Sixteen: Stocktake, Financial Regulation
In response to both the financial problems which occurred in the late 1980s
(such as increased loan default rates and heightened financial institution
distress) and the expansion of superannuation, prudential regulation was
upgraded through tougher capital requirements and structurally reformed through
consolidation, refocusing and better coordination of regulatory agencies. The
greater range and complexity of financial products and, in some areas, concerns
about more aggressive selling practices, have also led to an increased focus
upon consumer protection. This has resulted in new consumer credit regulation
and new rules for disclosure, codes of conduct and dispute resolution.
Globalisation has created an increasing need for global harmonisation of, and
cooperation in, the conduct of financial regulation. In the face of new
technologies, alliances and market structures, increased regulatory attention
has been given to ensuring competitive conduct in all segments of the market and
to providing a competitively neutral policy environment.
However, the ad hoc nature of some new regulation has created a quite expensive
regulatory framework. Over 800 staff are now involved in financial regulation in
Australia, resulting in direct and compliance costs which appear to be high by
international standards.
Chapter Seventeen: Stocktake, The Economy
While the difficulty of determining the effects of financial deregulation on the
economy has been noted, some observations can still be made. The removal of
exchange controls accelerated the integration of Australia with world capital
markets. This expanded the opportunities for both Australian-owned capital and
foreign-owned capital in Australia. In both cases this is likely to have been
beneficial to Australia.
Indeed, measures on productivity in the Australian economy suggest an upturn in
the 1990s, which has bolstered economic growth. This may be attributable in part
to greater efficiency resulting from financial deregulation.
However, the adjustment to a deregulated financial system was difficult, with a
credit boom and asset-price inflation generating a subsequent correction in the
early 1990s and associated bad debts and bankruptcies.
Exchange rate flexibility has increased Australian flexibility in responding to
economic shocks, while financial deregulation has restored the power of monetary
policy and allowed it to focus upon inflation control.
Increased scrutiny of government's economic policies by financial markets may be
viewed either as an undesirable constraint or as a desirable source of
discipline upon governments.
The weakness in national savings in the period since deregulation does not
appear to be strongly associated with deregulation, since it is due mainly to
low public sector savings, especially as a result of Commonwealth Government
budget deficits. Similarly, the impact of deregulation on long-term employment
seems small and is likely to be dominated by its impact on economic growth. It
cannot be blamed for enduring high levels of unemployment.
In this section we gather together some noteworthy arguments which can be, and
have been, made against some of the policy recommendations made in the Wallis
Report. This provides the counterbalance to the earlier sections which
summarised the Report's arguments and recommendations. These opposing arguments
are a 'smorgasbord of dissent' which are drawn from a variety of perspectives.
Some of the arguments and perspectives are in conflict with each other, so that,
as a whole, the following do not form a consistent, integrated set of
alternative policies.
Consumer Protection
The main policy position opposing the construction of the CFSC would seem to be
one advocating that consumer protection should be administered on an
economy-wide basis by the ACCC while regulation of corporations and financial
market integrity is done by another agency. We now present the main arguments in
support of this view.
The central advantage of an economy-wide regulator in any policy field is that
it can ensure standardisation of regulation across industry sectors and thus
achieve competitive neutrality. Here, the burden of regulation is born equally
by all industries affected, so that regulation does not create economic
distortions by favouring some sectors over others, and thus changing the
allocation of resources across industries. With more than one regulator in the
field, there is a consequent danger that regulation will not be standardised,
and differences in regulation will thus distort economic and commercial choices.
It could be argued that this danger is particularly relevant in the case where a
regulator for one sector of the economy is to be constructed, for here the
narrow focus of the specialised regulator's work, the corresponding focused
industry opposition to it, and its limited ability to generate political support
in other areas of the political economy, make it vulnerable to 'capture' by the
industry. Here, the standards of regulation will often be less rigorous and
demanding than for the rest of the economy, because the industry will ensure
that regulatory policy is 'industry friendly'.(6)
It could be argued that this scenario is very much applicable to the case of the
construction of the CFSC since it is envisaged that financial consumer
protection will be taken away from the ACCC, the formerly economy-wide
regulator, and given to a body which will not concern itself with consumer
protection in other industry sectors. This danger could be reinforced if the
CFSC is dominated by staff from the ASC who might thus have little interest in
consumer protection and concentrate on their other responsibilities, while
allowing financial consumer protection to be overly influenced by the wishes of
financial sector firms.(7)
The ACCC's well-known rigorous standards for consumer protection could thus be
watered down by the CFSC in relation to the financial system. Besides creating
inefficiencies, this outcome could also be interpreted as unfair by those who
regard rigorous consumer protection as a high social and political priority.
It could be argued that lodging the administration of all financial consumer
protection with the ACCC avoids these problems. A CFSC might still be formed but
its responsibilities would now resemble those of the currently existing ASC. As
such, the argument for any institutional reform in this area would become much
more tenuous.
The Mega Prudential Regulator
While there do not seem to be any substantial arguments against the formation of
one regulator for all DTIs, there are a couple of noteworthy arguments against
the formation of a single prudential regulator for the entire financial system.
First, it is clear that the nature of prudential regulation is different for
products where a commercial promise of a capital guarantee of funds has been
made (e.g. bank deposits) compared to products where no such promise has been
made and funds are deployed and used on a 'best-endeavours' basis, often by a
trustee structure (e.g. superannuation fund contributions). In the latter case,
there is no institutional promise that investment mistakes and market
fluctuations will not be sufficiently large as to wipe out some portion of the
capital value of the investments.
Prudential regulation is, and will continue to be, very different in these two
cases, and their conjoining in the one regulatory body will necessitate
different divisions within the regulator to cope with the very different demands
of regulation in the two classes of investments and institutions. This might
undermine the advantages of policy specialisation which arise from giving public
instrumentalities a few clear goals which they should pursue.(8) The greater the
complexity of the regulatory goals and practices set for any organisation the
greater the danger that it will not fulfil any of them terribly well but will do
only a minimally satisfactory job of each.
This might mean, for example, that the high standards of prudential bank
supervision achieved by the RBA could be compromised through the formation of
the APRC.
Second, it could be argued that the formation of the mega prudential regulator,
the APRC, will generate excessive expectations about the safety of investments
with non-deposit taking institutions especially. This might lead to problems of
'moral hazard' in which such investors and institutions engage in excessively
risky behaviour on the assumption that there is a government guarantee of any
investments made.(9) This could create the very sort of financial collapse that
prudential regulation is designed to avoid.
Large segments of the general public clearly believe that bank deposits are
currently guaranteed by the government through the RBA. Official spokespersons
may deny such a guarantee exists but it seems clear from mass financial
behaviour and public opinion poll responses that this belief exists. The
creation of a mega regulator might thus lead many individuals to believe that
this guarantee has been extended to all investments and institutions supervised
by the APRC. Such a belief might be quite immune to denials by official sources.
Indeed, the mere existence of such a belief could generate such powerful mass
political sentiments, at times of financial institution distress or collapse,
that governments are forced to step in and ensure that the retail investments in
question are fully refunded. This could place enormous pressure on the
Commonwealth Budget. Thus, it could be argued that the formation of an APRC will
vastly increase these implicit and contingent liabilities for the Commonwealth
Government, and thus, this regulatory change should be avoided.
One way to avoid such problems for the APRC might be to delete any explicit
reference to deposit protection, by any government agency, in its defining
legislation and to have this deletion well publicised by the Commonwealth and
APRC officers. Alternatively, such problems could also be avoided under an APRC
regime by ensuring that DTIs are clearly distinguished from non-DTIs, through
the use of explicit, and compulsory, deposit-insurance schemes in the former.
Such schemes are discussed later in this paper.
Separating Prudential Regulation from the RBA
There are a couple of noteworthy arguments against the view that prudential
regulation should be separated from the central bank.
First, it should be remembered that the Wallis Report proposes that provision of
emergency liquidity assistance to financial institutions in distress should
remain with the RBA and not be given as responsibility to the APRC. It could be
argued that this arrangement creates the danger that RBA decision-making
responses may be too slow in times of financial emergency, precisely because it
has not been dealing with the supervision of institutions on a continuing
day-to-day basis and is thus not sufficiently familiar with the cases of
financial distress which have arisen.
Placing RBA officers on the board of APRC reduces this danger somewhat, as would
the formation of a bilateral operational coordination committee, but only to the
extent that such RBA officers take their work with the APRC seriously and have
sufficient influence within the RBA during times of emergency that
decision-making is rapid enough to meet the needs of the institution in trouble.
If not, then slowness of provision of emergency funds might allow a basically
sound institution, in only temporary difficulties (e.g. in a 'solvent but
illiquid' situation), to collapse needlessly.(10)
This problem might be avoided by vesting control over emergency liquidity with
the prudential regulator, so that rapid response can match the need of the
institution for rapid emergency help. However, this raises questions of where
such funds are to be raised and what volumes of funds will be necessary to cope
with 'typical' problems of financial distress. One solution would be to give the
APRC power to quickly draw such emergency support funds from the RBA when the
former thought it necessary; here, the requests would be 'compulsory' in nature
(i.e. much more like instructions) and the RBA would not have the power to
delay, resist or refuse them.
Second, the separation of RBA responsibilities for monetary policy from
prudential regulation gives up completely on the possibility of the coordinated
deployment of monetary policy instruments (short-term nominal interest rates)
and prudential policy instruments (capital requirements, liquidity requirements,
etc.) to jointly achieve monetary policy goals and prudential soundness. That
is, monetary policy may sometimes be useful in achieving prudential goals (e.g.
in enhancing institutional soundness) while prudential policy may sometimes be
useful in achieving macroeconomic goals such as inflation control (e.g. by
affecting borrowing and lending flows).(11)
There may be many occasions where such joint usage of instruments in a
coordinated fashion will more effectively and efficiently achieve all these
goals than the narrow specialised targeting of one set of instruments on one
goal, as would occur under separation and as occurs now. Current RBA philosophy
and policy practice does not advocate such joint deployment of policy
instruments but this does not mean that such usage will not be possible in the
future. Such policy coordination would be very difficult to achieve when policy
is decided by two separate bodies.
Fees and Charges
The Report's recommendation that financial institutions be free to set fees and
charges at efficient, profitable levels could be challenged on the basis of the
following arguments.
Particularly in regard to transaction accounts, it could be argued that
financial institutions have a community service obligation of offering at least
the rudiments of low cost services, often called a Basic Banking Product (BBP).
These products are especially important to low-income, low-wealth customers of
financial institutions.(12) Such a BBP would allow the avoidance of fees below
some threshold of usage, provide regular account information, and also offer
some convenient and extensive bill-paying facility.
The nature of a BBP is such that its features necessarily imply that the
financial institution is not pricing such a product according to efficiency
principles of the marginal costs of operation. For example, efficient pricing
would not allow any fee-free threshold of usage because each account transaction
entails some cost to the institution which should, according to efficient and
profit-seeking pricing, have a fee attached to it.
Transaction accounts quite closely approximating the concept of a BBP are now
offered by the banks. These were introduced in the aftermath of the issue of the
report by the former Prices Surveillance Authority in 1995 on the subject.(13)
They offer, for example, a fee-free range of usage, in exchange for generally
not having to pay interest on account balances.(14) It now remains to be seen
whether they continue to be offered or are withdrawn in response to the coming
policy changes which the Wallis Report will generate.
It is generally agreed that other policy approaches to providing a BBP,
especially for low-income and low-wealth customers, can be more economically
efficient than the operation of the budget accounts described above. One obvious
option is to use the tax/ transfer system to subsidise the account usage of such
disadvantaged customers. Here, account pricing could be efficiently set but this
would not reduce the real incomes of such customers, who will be recompensed for
such costs. The Wallis Report advocates the further study of such compensation
schemes.
However, the current reality of fiscal politics at the Commonwealth level is
that ongoing moves to budgetary tightening over the next few years will almost
certainly preclude the introduction of such schemes. Even in the medium to long
term, the likelihood of such an introduction may be slight, given the many other
claims which will be made upon the Commonwealth's revenue and spending systems.
In this situation, it could be argued that the Commonwealth should ensure that
such basic transaction accounts continue to be offered by legislating to force
all deposit taking institutions to offer them.(15) The inefficiencies entailed
in such compulsion would probably be small so long as institutions continued to
offer a range of other accounts which had economically efficient pricing
policies attached to them.
Access Points to Financial Institutions
Similar arguments can also be made in regard to the convenience of access to
financial services. The Report argues that substantial cost savings are possible
if financial institutions rationalise their distribution systems so that high
cost channels of distribution, such as bank branches, undergo some contraction
while low cost channels, such as ATMs, undergo expansion. These changes will
come about, both through direct management decisions by the institutions and as
an automatic result of more efficient and cost relevant pricing of distribution
channels. Branch transactions should be more expensive, in relative terms, while
electronic transactions should become cheaper in relative terms.
The contrary argument would be that financial institutions have a community
service obligation to provide a reasonable spread of their distribution
channels, both in terms of geographic distribution and in terms of offering a
range of types of transactions. This would mean that the configuration of
distribution points should not just be determined by efficiency and cost
considerations but also by the needs of the community. Thus, it could be argued
that governments should liaise with financial institutions and apply relevant
incentives and pressures to them to ensure a sufficiently wide and varied
distribution system for financial services.
In particular, this argument probably implies that the branch systems of
financial institutions should not be allowed to fall below some minimum breadth
of coverage and that the fees attached to branch transactions should not be
allowed to rise above some threshold. Alternatively, the provision of basic
transaction accounts discussed earlier could be designed so that some branch
transactions were always included as a part of the fee-free range of usage.
In regard to branches, this argument could imply allowing, or encouraging,
explicit cooperation amongst financial institutions so that towns and suburbs
were left with at least one or two of their branches for the use of customers,
even if the full range of institutions was no longer present in each of
them.(16) This would allow cost savings for the financial system as a whole
while preserving a minimum level of financial services.
The Six Pillars Policy
The Wallis Report recommended that the prohibition on mergers between the
largest banks and life offices be abandoned so that the ACCC will be the sole
competition policy regulator in these matters. The Commonwealth Government has
already announced that while it now does not, in principle, oppose mergers
between any life office and any bank, it will still maintain the ban on mergers
between the four largest banks until such time as competition in key areas such
as finance for SMEs, and transactions accounts, has intensified
substantially.(17)
Many sections of the community support the Government's move since they hold
substantial grounds for disquiet over further bank mergers at a time when newly
released competitive forces are just finding a foothold in a quite concentrated
financial system. While it appears somewhat unlikely that the ACCC would have
approved such proposed mergers if allowed to, it can be argued that the issue is
of such national importance that it warrants the Government's continued
pre-emptive overriding of any ACCC views on these matters.
The operational autonomy of regulatory bodies is of considerable importance for
good public policymaking, but on matters of high national interest it could be
argued to be perfectly valid and proper for the elected government of the day to
take matters into their own hands and make binding decisions, for which they
will be answerable to the general public at the next election. This principle
could also be applied to matters of high importance in regulatory matters
conducted by other financial system bodies, such as the prudential regulator or
the consumer protection agency.
Foreign Ownership
The Report's somewhat half-hearted support for, and ambivalent attitude towards,
higher direct foreign investment in the Australian financial system, could be
challenged from perspectives both of being too hostile to foreign investment,
and then of being too trusting and naive in its attitude to foreign investment.
The Report's position on this issue has been largely adopted by the Commonwealth
Government.(18)
As the Report notes, direct foreign investment in the financial system can bring
with it the substantial benefits of new capital, skills, technologies and
intensified competition. It might also lay the foundation for the outward
expansion of Australian financial institutions into new markets. This, in turn,
could generate benefits for their Australian operations in terms of economies of
scale and world-best-practice operational efficiency.
However, the Report's warning that a substantial increase in foreign ownership
would be against the national interest, because it might close off options for
future development of the financial sector, could be viewed as fundamentally
inconsistent with the great bulk of the arguments and recommendations it makes.
The Report is very much in the mould of advocating greater freedom for market
forces to improve efficiency and productivity in the financial system. However,
in relation to foreign investment it proposes the continuation of restrictions
which have the effect of shielding the sector, in large part, from the full
force of international investor competition.
If, for example, all DTIs in Australia were open to takeover by overseas
financial institutions then they would face intensified pressure for continued
good performance in order to be able to ward off such potential threats to their
independence.(19) This attitude of the Report on the dangers of foreign
investment could thus be viewed as somewhat paradoxical. Indeed, this very
principle which supports investment restrictions might be applied to many other
sectors of the economy and become the justification for imposing substantial
restrictions on direct foreign investment there. But clearly, it is not at all
the intention of the Wallis Committee that its argument should be used in this
way.
It is also interesting to note that the Report is silent on specific foreign
investment issues such as whether foreign bank branches should be allowed to
enter retail markets directly by accepting small retail deposits in their
Australian operations. The foreign banks which initially flowed into Australia
in the 1980s were required to set up locally incorporated subsidiaries in order
to facilitate full prudential supervision by the RBA. The previous Commonwealth
Government allowed foreign banks to set up branches (i.e. directly controlled
divisions of their foreign parent bank) operating in wholesale markets but not
in retail markets. One concern about foreign bank branches operating in retail
markets has been that in the case of their collapse and liquidation there might
be substantial doubt about Australian depositors having any sort of preference
over other creditors in the final distribution of remaining assets after
liquidation.(20)
Overall, it might be viewed as indicative of the Report's rather strange
treatment of foreign investment that it failed to address this important current
policy issue.
Of course, the Report can also be criticised from the opposite perspective that
foreign ownership of key national assets such as its largest banks and insurance
companies should not be allowed at all, for the Report's very own reason that it
would close off options for future development of these industries in ways which
might be against the long-term national interest of Australia. From this
perspective, at the very least, foreign investors in these sectors should be
subject to rigorous performance criteria to ensure that Australia gets a good
share of the benefits which their presence might generate.(21)
Deposit Insurance
Finally, the Report's abandonment of the idea of explicit deposit insurance for
retail customers could be challenged. Such schemes are quite widely used
throughout the world, in both advanced and developing countries.(22)
As the Committee notes, the great advantage of such explicit, compulsory
insurance schemes is that they give retail customers certainty that their
deposits with financial institutions are completely safe. This would remove any
lingering doubts about the current system which the Report describes as ensuring
that the chances of losing depositors' funds is remote, rather than being zero.
This certainty promotes policy transparency and provides a good environment in
which efficient customer choices can be made about the allocation of their
wealth amongst assets of differing risk and return characteristics. It also
provides a social equity value of safety for customers, especially low-income
ones, seeking full security and unable to judge the varying security of the
financial institutions on offer in terms of retail accounts. Thus, it furthers
both efficiency and equity as financial outcomes.
After consideration of overseas schemes and the role of deposit insurance in the
savings and loan fiasco in the United States, the Committee concluded that, for
Australian financial circumstances, it was unable to devise insurance schemes
which would not undermine incentives for institutions to take proper care of
their depositors' funds. Thus, it dropped the idea.
However, it is well known that there are ways of designing such insurance
schemes which encourage prudent use of deposit funds by institutions.(23) These
are schemes where the insurance premiums to be paid by institutions (either to
public or private insurers) vary with the risk profile of the assets of the
institution, with more risky lending to business, for example, attracting higher
premiums than for other types of lending. Such insurance schemes have some
likeness to the risk-weighted capital adequacy rules now widely applied by bank
regulators throughout the advanced world, where more risky lending requires
greater capital backing in order to better protect deposit funds from the
greater dangers of default in these cases.
There have also been doubts expressed, in the Report and elsewhere, about
whether governments will have the political will and commercial and actuarial
sense to price the insurance premiums at levels that will fully cover any likely
payouts from institutional collapse. There are two options to address this
issue. First, for insurance schemes operated by governments, they could call
upon private insurance expertise in designing and operating these schemes so
that they are financially and actuarially sound. Second, governments could
completely 'contract out' such insurance schemes by simply requiring all deposit
taking institutions to take out private insurance to cover the refund of
deposits in the event that the institution collapses and is put into
liquidation.
Such insurance could be capped at some account balance level, for social equity
reasons of ensuring that insurance payouts do not disproportionately benefit the
wealthy. Other prudential regulatory measures aimed at deposit protection could
be simplified and relaxed, in order to help institutions pay for such insurance
premiums. Thus, it could be viewed as disappointing that the Wallis Committee
did not investigate these insurance options in much more depth.
It is interesting to note that deposit insurance could provide a neat solution
to the safety problems surrounding foreign bank branches in Australia. Such
branches could be allowed to accept retail deposits provided they were insured.
This would facilitate the benefits of the extra competition that branches would
bring while at the same time guaranteeing full security, up to the capped level,
for such retail deposits.
Conduct and Disclosure
1 Corporations Law, market integrity and consumer protection should be combined
in a single agency, the Corporations and Financial Services Commission (CFSC).
2 The CFSC should have comprehensive responsibilities.
3 The CFSC should administer all consumer protection laws for financial
services.
4 Due diligence defences should apply to positive disclosure requirements.
5 The CFSC and the ACCC should coordinate examination of financial exchange
rules.
6 States and Territories should retain and review consumer credit laws.
7 The CFSC should have powers to use a combination of regulatory approaches.
8 Disclosure requirements should be consistent and comparable.
9 Profile statements should be introduced for more effective disclosure.
10 Shorter prospectuses should be encouraged.
11 Financial institutions' financial reports should meet Corporations Law and
prudential requirements.
12 Accounting standards should be harmonised with international standards.
13 A single licensing regime should be introduced for financial sales, advice
and dealing.
14 The CFSC should have power to delegate accreditation responsibilities to
industry bodies.
15 A single set of requirements should be introduced for financial sales and
advice.
16 Regulation of real estate agents providing financial advice should be
reviewed.
16 Licensing of professionals providing incidental financial advice is generally
not required.
18 Additional prudential regulation of financial market licence holders is not
required.
19 Broader regulation of 'financial products' should replace current securities
and futures law.
20 Prohibitions on retail participation in over-the-counter (OTC) derivative
markets should be discontinued.
21 The CFSC should authorise financial exchanges under a single regime.
22 Regulation of exchanges should not be excessive compared with OTC markets.
23 OTC markets may be conducted by appropriately licensed intermediaries.
24 Exchange clearing houses should be appropriately authorised.
25 A central gateway for dispute resolution should be established.
26 Coverage of dispute resolution schemes should be broader.
27 The CFSC should have broad enforcement powers.
28 The CFSC should monitor new technologies.
29 The CFSC should participate in global regulatory programs.
Financial Safety
30 Prudential regulation should be imposed on deposit taking, insurance and
superannuation.
31 A single Commonwealth prudential regulator, the Australian Prudential
Regulation Commission (APRC), should be established.
32 The APRC should be separate from, but cooperate closely with, the Reserve
Bank of Australia (RBA).
33 The APRC should have comprehensive powers to meet its regulatory objectives.
34 The intensity of prudential regulation needs to balance financial safety and
efficiency.
35 Prudential regulation of DTIs needs to be consistent with international
requirements.
36 A single DTI licensing regime should be introduced.
37 Deposit taking by unlicensed entities should be restricted and regulated by
the CFSC.
38 The APRC should regulate life companies.
39 Regulation of friendly societies should be transferred to the Commonwealth.
40 The APRC should regulate general insurers.
41 The APRC should regulate superannuation in accordance with retirement
objectives.
41 Compliance by excluded funds should be monitored by the Australian Taxation
Office.
43 Other APRC regulated institutions should have the right to offer retirement
savings accounts.
44 The APRC should promote more transparent disclosure.
45 The principle of spread of ownership should be retained and regulation
rationalised.
46 The approach to sectoral separation needs to be more flexible.
47 Mutual entities should be permitted to hold all classes of licences.
48 New entrants should be subject to minimum capital and other requirements.
49 Non-operating holding companies should be permitted subject to certain
requirements.
50 Multiple licences and other financial activities may be permitted.
51 The APRC should be empowered to access operations of other non-regulated
entities in the group.
52 Fundraising by money market corporations should be subject to CFSC
surveillance.
53 Fundraising by finance companies should be subject to CFSC surveillance.
54 There should be appropriate mechanisms for resolving failure of DTIs.
55 There should be appropriate mechanisms for resolving failure of insurance and
superannuation.
Stability and Payments
56 The RBA should remain responsible for system stability.
57 The CFSC should be responsible for regulation of financial exchanges.
58 Regulatory agencies should monitor wholesale markets.
59 The RBA should promote control of domestic and international settlement
risks.
60 Liquidity management responses should remain the responsibility of the RBA.
61 A Payments System Board should be formed within the RBA.
62 Membership of the PSB should reflect payments system efficiency objectives.
63 The PSB should set performance benchmarks.
64 The RBA's commercial activities should be clearly separated from regulatory
responsibilities.
65 The Australian Payments System Council should be disbanded.
66 Rights to issues cheques should be extended.
67 Interchange arrangements should be reviewed by the PSB and the ACCC.
68 The ACCC should maintain a watching brief over the rules of international
credit card associations.
69 Access to clearing systems should be liberalised.
70 The Australian Payments Clearing Association should continue its role in
clearing arrangements with wider membership.
71 The Trade Practices Act should continue to apply to payments clearing
arrangements.
72 Stores of value for payment instruments should be subject to regulation.
73 Access to ESAs should be liberalised subject to appropriate conditions.
74 Highvalue payments settlement providers should be regulated to the
international standard for banks.
75 Non-deposit takers should be able to settle directly consumer electronic and
bulk electronic payments.
76 RTGS system benchmarks should be established.
77 The PSB should issue payments system approvals.
78 The PSB and the APRC should establish close coordination arrangements.
Mergers and Acquisitions
79 Section 50 of the Trade Practices Act should continue to apply to the
financial system.
80 The ACCC should administer competition laws for the financial system.
81 The prudential regulator should assess the prudential implications of
relevant mergers and acquisitions.
82 The Trade Practices Act should provide the only competition regulation of
financial system mergers.
83 The 'six pillars' policy should be removed.
84 Merger assessments should take account of changes occurring in the sector.
85 General foreign investment policy should apply to the financial system.
Promoting Increased Efficiency
86 Foreign investment regulations for the funds management industry should be
reviewed.
87 Takeover and merger provisions are needed for collective investments.
88 Superannuation fund members should have greater choice of fund.
89 Regulation of collective investments and public offer superannuation should
be harmonised.
90 Regulation of trustee companies should be modernised and applied on a uniform
national basis.
91 Legislation should be amended to allow for electronic commerce.
92 Australia should adopt international standards for electronic commerce.
93 International harmonisation of law enforcement and consumer protection should
be pursued.
94 Regulators should coordinate on technology.
95 Institutions should have freedom to set fees and charges based on costs.
96 Governments should examine alternative means of providing lowcost transaction
services.
97 Superannuation funds should not be required to invest in small and medium
sized enterprises.
98 Data collection on SMEs should consider the needs of rating agencies and fund
managers.
99 A working party on positive credit reporting should be established.
100 Information sharing among group entities should be allowed unless the
customer withdraws consent.
101 The extension of the privacy regime should follow a number of principles.
102 The Housing Loans Insurance Corporation should be privatised.
Coordination and Accountability
103 Regulatory agencies should have operational autonomy.
104 Regulatory agencies' charges should reflect their costs.
105 Interest on noncallable deposits should be reviewed.
106 Regulatory agencies should set their charges, subject to approval by the
Treasurer.
107 Regulatory agencies should be offbudget.
108 Regulatory agencies should have boards, with majorities of independent
directors.
109 Regulatory agencies should improve their reporting.
110 A Financial Sector Advisory Council should be created.
111 Regulatory agencies need power to exchange information.
112 The Council of Financial Regulators should coordinate a broad range of
activities.
Managing Change
113 A staged approach to change is required.
114 A panel for uniform commercial laws should be established.
115 There is a proposed sequence for implementing the recommendations.
- Australian
Financial System Inquiry, Final
Report (Campbell Report),
Canberra: Australian Government Publishing Service, 1981.
- Australian
Financial System Review Group, Report (Martin
Review Report), Canberra: Australian Government Publishing Service, 1984.
- Australia,
Parliament of Australia, A
Pocket Full of Change: Banking and Deregulation, Report
of the House of Representatives Standing Committee on Finance and Public
Administration (Martin Report), Canberra: Australian Government Publishing
Service, November 1991.
- Industry
Commission, Availability
of Capital, Report No. 18. Canberra: Australian Government Publishing
Service, December, 1991.
- Australian
Financial System Inquiry, Final
Report (Wallis Report),
Canberra: Australian Government Publishing Service, March 1997.
- Paul Kelly, 'The
Wallis Revolution', Australian,
12-13 April 1997; Tom Burton, 'Wallis: Now for the Hard Yards', Australian
Financial Review, 11 April 1997.
- Andrew Cornell,
'Consumer Groups Rally to ACCC', Australian
Financial Review, 11 April 1997; Bryan Frith, 'Building on ASC Powers
the Logical Post-Wallis Choice', Australian,
11 April 1997.
- The Martin
Report, A
Pocket Full of Change, Canberra: Australian Government Publishing
Service, November 1991: 236; Australian Financial System Inquiry, Discussion
Paper, Canberra: Australian Government Publishing Service, November
1996: 207.
- The Martin
Report, A
Pocket Full of Change, Canberra: Australian Government Publishing
Service, November 1991: 237; Australian Financial System Inquiry, Discussion
Paper, Canberra: Australian Government Publishing Service, November
1996: 207. See also: Alan Mitchell, 'Foreigners to Inject Competition', Australian
Financial Review, 10 April 1997; Joanne Gray, 'RBA Bites Hard on
Prudential Loss', Australian
Financial Review, 11 April
1997.
- The Martin
Report, A
Pocket Full of Change, Canberra: Australian Government Publishing
Service, November 1991: 227; Australian Financial System Inquiry, Discussion
Paper, Canberra: Australian Government Publishing Service, November
1996: 211; and Joanne Gray, 'MacFarlane Warns of Wallis Side Effects', Australian
Financial Review, 9 May 1997.
- Tom Valentine,
'Larger Issues Unresolved', Australian
Financial Review, 10 April 1997.
- Toby O'Connor,
'No Bank Fees Please-We're Too Poor', Australian,
17 April 1997.
- Prices
Surveillance Authority, Inquiry
into Fees and Charges Imposed on Retail Accounts by Banks and Other
Financial Institutions and by Retailers on EFTPOS Transactions,
Canberra: Australian Government Publishing Service, June 1995.
- Phil Hanratty, Fees
and Charges on 'Budget' Bank Accounts, Department of the Parliamentary
Library, Information and Research Services, Research Note No. 28, February
1997.
- Editorial,
'Colonial Sets Test for Banks', Australian
Financial Review, 18 April 1997.
- Phil Hanratty, Bank
Branch Rationalisation: Should We Allow or Encourage Limited Cooperation ?, Department
of the Parliamentary Library, Parliamentary Research Service, Research Note
No. 11, November 1996.
- Australia,
Parliament of Australia, Treasurer (Peter Costello), 'Release of the Report
of the Financial System Inquiry and Initial Government Response on Mergers
Policy', Press
Release No. 28, 9 April
1997: 2.
- Ibid: 2.
- Editorial, 'Open
Door for Foreign Banks', Australian
Financial Review, 4 April 1997.
- Phil Hanratty, Foreign
Bank Policy in Australia, Department of the Parliamentary Library,
Parliamentary Research Service, Current Issues Brief No. 8, November 1995.
- Phil Hanratty, Inward
Direct Foreign Investment in Australia: Policy Controls and Economic
Outcomes, Department of the
Parliamentary Library, Parliamentary Research Service, Research Paper No.
32, May 1996: 20-21.
- The Martin
Report, A
Pocket Full of Change, Canberra: Australian Government Publishing
Service, November 1991: 211-213.
- Gillian Garcia, Deposit
Insurance: Obtaining the Benefits and Avoiding the Pitfalls,
Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund, Working Paper No. 83, August
1996: 33.
|