| |
CRIME AND JUSTICE Bulletin
NSW Bureau of Crime Statistics and Research
October 2004
The deterrent effect of capital punishment: A review of the research evidence
Janet Chan and Deborah Oxley,
School of Social Science and Policy, University of New South Wales
Capital punishment has been abolished in all Australian States since the mid
1980s. The United States of America is the only Western democracy that has
retained the death penalty. The aim of this bulletin is to analyse and summarise
the empirical evidence on the deterrent effect of capital punishment. It
provides a survey of the results of 74 research projects published between 1952
and 2003. These projects employed a variety of methodologies, including economic
modelling, and covered a range of geographical areas and time periods mainly in
the United States. The majority of the studies show that the use of capital
punishment did not deter the commission of homicide; this remains the case when
studies that used relatively unsophisticated research designs were excluded. The
bulletin concludes that three decades of deterrence research since Ehrlich’s
(1975a) economic model has failed to deliver conclusive evidence on the
deterrent effect of capital punishment.
1. INTRODUCTION
Capital punishment – the state- sanctioned termination of a criminal
offender’s life, usually for a serious violent offence – is a topic which raises
many issues and emotions. Among Western democracies, the United States is the
only country that has retained the death penalty.
Capital punishment for any form of
murder was abolished in the UK in 1965 and in Canada in 1976. In Australia, all
States had abolished capital punishment by 1984 – the last executions took place
in the mid 1960s (Potas and Walker 1987). There has not been any
indication that a reversal of this policy is being contemplated. Nevertheless,
with high-profile international cases of
terrorism and war crime being brought to justice, capital punishment has once
again come to the forefront of public consciousness.
Historically, the use of different forms of punishment is driven by a range of
social, cultural and political factors, often quite unrelated to the
effectiveness of these sanctions for crime control (Beattie 1986; Garland 1990).
As many have argued, the use of capital punishment is predominantly a political
and moral issue: ‘the crucial question … concerns its legitimacy and propriety,
rather than its efficacy’ (Zimring and Hawkins 1986, p. 167). In the United
States at least, the decision to use or abolish capital punishment has never
been based on a dispassionate assessment of the research evidence regarding its
efficacy; rather, research is used by people with committed views to support
their convictions or discredit opponents (ibid., p. 184). Indeed, analysts of
policymaking have found that when opinions are sharply divided, research is
often used to ‘supply evidence that will reassure supporters, convince the
undecided, and weaken rivals’ positions’ (Weiss 1991, p. 41; see also Majone
1989). However, this political use of knowledge at times of conflict does not
preclude the possibility that research evidence can be used in a more positive
way to clarify issues and inform policy, especially where there is a broad
societal consensus regarding values and goals (Weiss 1991).
There is by now a vast literature of
empirical research on the deterrent effect of capital punishment, often pointing
to quite opposite conclusions. Some of the research studies involve
statistical models that are highly technical and inaccessible to the general
reader. The sheer volume of publications on the topic is itself a barrier to an
informed public opinion on the research evidence.
The aim of this bulletin is to analyse
and summarize this evidence in as accessible a way as possible, without
oversimplifying or omitting key issues. The focus of this literature review is
on one specific question: how effective is capital punishment in preventing
others from committing a similar crime? In other words, does the threat of a
death penalty deter people from crime?
This bulletin is organized as follows. We will briefly discuss the theory of
deterrence and the history of capital punishment in the rest of this section.
Section 2 discusses the techniques researchers have used to assess the deterrent
effect of capital punishment. Section 3 provides a survey of the research
evidence based on a review of 74 research projects published between 1952 and
2003. Besides presenting research findings on the deterrent effect of capital
punishment, we also briefly discuss some of the unintended consequences brought
about by the use of capital punishment.
In Section 4 we summarize the research evidence and present our conclusions.
THEORY OF DETERRENCE
Before considering the effectiveness of capital punishment, it is important
to describe, in specific terms, the underlying theory of deterrence.
Deterrence, in its simplest definition, is
an effect where a threat of punishment ‘causes individuals who would have
committed the threatened behaviour
to refrain from doing so’ (Zimring and Hawkins 1973, p. 71). A common
distinction is drawn between individual or special deterrence, which refers to
the deterrent effect of punishment on the individual who was punished, and
general deterrence, which refers to
the ‘inhibiting effect of sanctions on
the criminal activity of people other than the sanctioned offender’ (National
Research Council Panel on Deterrent and Incapacitative Effects 1978, quoted by
Zimring and Hawkins 1986, p. 171). For obvious reasons, only general deterrence
is at issue as far as capital punishment is concerned. Another important
distinction is that between absolute deterrence and marginal deterrence – the
former compares the effect of one form or level of punishment with the effect of
no punishment, while the latter compares the effect of one form or level of
punishment against another. Again, it is obvious that with research on capital
punishment, it is not absolute deterrence that is of interest, but marginal
deterrence. In other words, the crucial question is whether capital punishment
is a more effective deterrent than an alternative option such as life
imprisonment.
How is deterrence supposed to work? Zimring and Hawkins (1973) have argued that
deterrence may work in one or more of the following ways:
1. Simple deterrence – the threat of punishment can cause a ‘change of heart’ in
a person who is about to commit a crime. This change of heart is the result of
weighing up the ‘pleasure’ of committing the crime with the risk of the pain of
punishment. This is the main source of deterrence.
2. Punishment as a moralising force – the threat of punishment conveys the
degree of disapproval that society has placed on the crime; this disapproval has
an effect on the moral attitudes of people and hence their behaviours.
3. Punishment as a habit builder –
the threat of punishment can induce and reinforce compliant behaviours to the
point that people observe the law as a matter of habit.
4. Punishment builds respect for the law – the fact that people cannot break the
law with impunity builds respect for the law and the legal system and therefore
reduces law-breaking.
5. Punishment as a rationale for conformity – the existence of the threat of
punishment can provide a reason for conformity, especially when a person is
subject to group pressure.
The deterrent effect of punishment can be affected by its certainty – the extent
to which the threat of punishment is realized in practice, its celerity – the
swiftness with which punishment is delivered and its severity – the level of
‘pain’ imposed (Tittle 1969).
HISTORY OF DEATH AND DISCRETION
As a background to a review of contemporary research into the efficacy of
capital punishment for crime control, it is important to be aware of its
historical roots and be informed by the issues this history raised. Capital
punishment has a long history – for most of the last millennium, it was the
primary judicial sanction in England, a country whose institutions have
influenced many others. British imperial expansion into America and Australia
carried with it a legal code founded on the death sentence. Punishment was not
graded beyond a simple division into minor and major crime. While a minor
offence – a misdemeanour – was punishable by a whipping, fine, or a few days in
the local gaolhouse, all felonies were capital (Radzinowicz 1948-86).
Felonies included crimes of treason, murder and rape, but also included property
crimes such as robbery, burglary and simple grand larceny: the theft of property
worth more than one shilling (without aggravating circumstances). Faith in
capital punishment was governed less by a belief that it deterred crime than by
the conviction that eliminating an offender restored society’s health, just as
the
body was restored by the amputation of an infected limb (McGowen 1987). The
death sentence was not supplemented by any ‘secondary’ punishments until the
rise of penal transportation in the 18th century and imprisonment in the 19th
century. The necessary precursor to these developments was an intellectual shift
which embraced concepts of graduated punishment and of the human potential for
reform.
Inflicting the death sentence on most crimes should, at least in theory, have
led to a very high execution rate.
Mitigating the severity of this code was
the Benefit of Clergy, described as ‘the massive fiction that tempered in
practice the harshness of the common law rule that virtually all felonies were
capital offences’ (Beattie 1986, p. 141).
Originally an exemption for clerics allowing them to be punished by an
ecclesiastical court, the Benefit of Clergy had broadened over the 14th and 15th
centuries to forestall the death penalty for lay people who were deemed to be
literate (as assessed by the use of a reading test). Initially, offenders could
be granted the benefit on more than one occasion, but by the 15th century, this
form of reprieve was limited to one instance only (at least in theory).
To guarantee that offenders did not receive the benefit twice, when guilty
felons were granted benefit, they were branded with a ‘T’ for thief or ‘M’ for
murderer (Beattie 1986). By 1706, the reading test was abolished, in effect
permitting the discharge of illiterate felons (ibid, p. 142).
This apparent softening of the system was accompanied by an opposing
trend which began in the 15th century
and continued for the next 300 years whereby certain offences were reclassified
as ‘non-clergyable’. A flurry of legislation over the 18th century widened the
definition of property crime, creating over 200 capital statutes that together
came to be known as England’s ‘Bloody Code’ (Beattie 1986, Jones 1982, Thompson
1975).
The code was censured by contemporaries for its inhumanity and for brutalizing
society (McGowen 1986).
Executions were public spectacles
and were increasingly criticized as sanctioning violence and undermining state
authority, especially in cases where spectators’ sympathy lay with the
condemned. The second main criticism, and the one that would carry legal reform,
was that the widespread use of capital punishment was
ineffective. Without graded punishment, the rational offender ‘might as well
be hung for a sheep as a lamb’. Prosecution (already private and costly) was
uncommon because many
victims were reticent to see thieves and robbers hang (Shubert 1981). Juries
demonstrated similar qualms,
enthusiastically finding ‘partial verdicts’. The seriousness of a property crime
was measured by the value of the goods stolen; in a partial verdict, the jury
found the defendant guilty of a crime of lesser value than their indictment,
thus reclassifying the offence as a misdemeanour subject to a different
punishment regime (Beattie 1986).
Judges, too, had wide discretionary powers in sentencing and in granting
pardons. Even though an average of 66 capital convictions were passed every year
between 1701 and 1834 at the Old Bailey central criminal court, there were, on
average, only 16 executions (Gatrell 1994, p. 616). What distinguished the 16
who would hang from the other 50 is unclear, and was no doubt equally
bewildering to those awaiting news of their impending punishment. The whole
system was unpredictable and based on an arbitrary use of discretion (Hay,
Linebaugh and Thompson 1975, King 2000). Criticisms that the legal code was
ineffectual and brutalizing gained political ground as other aspects of criminal
justice were reformed: the rise of modern policing, publicly funded
prosecutions, and alternative and graduated punishments. In the space
of 20 years, the Bloody Code was dismantled, with only murder and treason
remaining as capital offences in 1841.
In Britain, the abolition of capital punishment for murder continued to be
debated for over a century (see, for example, Bailey 2000) but was finally
removed from the statutes in
1965. It was at this time that Australia relinquished the use of the death
penalty. Shortly after, in 1968, the US refrained from exercising this form of
punishment, and in 1972, the US Supreme Court ruled that capital punishment was
unconstitutional.
A moratorium on capital punishment followed. When four years later the same
court changed its position by deciding that some executions were
constitutionally acceptable, it set the stage for States to decide whether to
reintroduce executions. The moratorium and subsequent reinstatement of the death
penalty in some States created the conditions of a ‘natural experiment’ on the
deterrent effects of this form of punishment. By 2000, 13 jurisdictions
(including the District of Columbia) had decided against reintroducing the death
penalty; 7 States had reintroduced the death penalty but had not used it; a
further 24 States had used it infrequently (less than once per year); and 7
States somewhat more frequently, ranging from South Carolina where 25 people
were executed post-moratorium, to Texas with 239 executions (Snell 2001). Not
surprisingly, the US has become the focus for research on the deterrent effects
of capital punishment.
2. TECHNIQUES FOR ASSESSING THE DETERRENT EFFECT OF CAPITAL PUNISHMENT
The research literature on the deterrent effect of capital punishment is
extensive. Our collection is based on keyword searches using the available
library databases and a compilation of bibliographic references used by authors
in publications. It covers all the major publications cited in reviews such as
those carried out by Hood (2002) and Zimring and Hawkins (1986), as well as
those referred to in more recent publications. A total of 74 separate empirical
studies were identified. These form the basis of the survey, the findings of
which will be discussed in Section 3. In this Section we briefly describe the
range of techniques used in the literature for assessing the deterrent effect of
capital punishment, and discuss the major methodological and theoretical issues
that require attention for the research evidence to be appropriately
interpreted.
TYPES OF ANALYSIS
As Hood (2002) has pointed out, the research literature is almost exclusively
focused on the use of capital punishment for murder. The vast majority of
studies have been conducted in the United States of America, where the death
penalty is widely practised (see, however, Avio 1979 and Layson 1983 for
Canadian studies and Wolpin 1978 for a UK study). The United States provides
favourable conditions for empirical research on capital punishment for at least
two reasons: first, differential adoption of capital punishment among States
provides natural variations for cross-sectional analysis (i.e., comparison
across States); and second, the ten-year moratorium (1968-1977) on executions
set up a ‘natural experiment’ for comparing the effectiveness of different
punishment regimes. In general, research studies are based on one or more of the
following designs (see Hood 2002):
1. Simple Before/After Comparisons
This design helps researchers assess whether the abolition or introduction of
capital punishment within a particular jurisdiction has led to an increase or
decrease in the rate of murder. Examples of this design include Barber and
Wilson (1968), Samuelson (1969), and Archer, Gartner and Beittel (1983).
2. Cross-Jurisdiction Comparisons
This design allows researchers to compare murder rates within a fixed period of
time between jurisdictions that have abolished capital punishment with those
that have retained or reintroduced it.
Comparison is usually made relative complexity, and the increasing proportion of
research studies using econometric models, we will explain this approach in some
detail below.
ECONOMIC MODELS OF DETERRENCE
Ehrlich (1972; 1973) was the first
to make use of an econometric model to analyse the deterrent effect of criminal
law enforcement. His approach (Ehrlich
Figure 1: Ehrlich’s Model 1975a) has since been used by a long line of
researchers with minor modifications (Layson 1983, Dezhbakhsh, Rubin and
Shepherd 2003). Figure 1 provides a simplified explanation of Ehrlich’s
framework as
described by Barnett (1978, pp. 292-293
and 302-303). Essentially, the model consists of a mathematical equation that
links the ‘average unhappiness’ of a potential murderer with the risks of being
arrested, being convicted
between jurisdictions that are similar in social, demographic and economic
characteristics.
Some studies are based on simple
statistics on homicide rates; others calculate correlation coefficients between
execution and homicide rates. Examples include Sellin (1959), Lempert (1983),
and
Cheatwood (1993).
3. Short-Term Effect of Executions
The effect of well-publicized or notorious executions on subsequent murder rates
is assessed using
a simple before/after comparison, usually over a short time period (days or
weeks) before and after the execution. Examples of these studies include Savitz
(1958), McFarland (1983), Grogger (1990)
and Thomson (1999).
4. Multiple Regression Using Time- Series, Cross-Sectional and/or Panel Data
The design makes use of linear economic models to estimate the impact of
executions on
homicides over time and/or across jurisdictions, while ‘controlling for’ a range
of social and legal variables. Examples include Ehrlich (1975a), Passell (1975),
Dezhbakhsh, Rubin, & Sheperd (2003) and many others.
Earlier studies of the deterrent effect of capital punishment generally made use
of the first three designs, while later studies have tended to employ multiple
regression models. Because of its
EHRLICH’S ANALYIS OF A RATIONAL MURDERER’S ASSESSMENT OF THE RELATIVE
IMPORTANCE OF DIFFERENT PUNISHMENT-RISK VARIABLES
If a person commits a murder, four possible consequences related to punishment
can arise:
(1) No arrest, thus no punishment
(2) Arrest, but no conviction for homicide
(3) Arrest, conviction for homicide, some non-lethal punishment
(4) Arrest, conviction, execution.
Let
p(a) = Probability of arrest for a randomly chosen homicide
p(c|a) = Probability of conviction for homicide given arrest for homicide
p(e|c) = Probability of execution given conviction for homicide
Suppose the number Ui is a measure of a potential murderer’s happiness (utility)
if outcome i occurs. If the person in question is rational, Ehrlich conjectures,
the numbers U1, U2, U3, U4 will be decreasing. (The last three could presumably
be negative.) Let pi be the probability that the murder will result in outcomei.
The pi’s
are related to the risk-variables p(a), p(c|a), p(e|c) defined earlier by the
equations:
p = 1 - p(a)
= p(a)(1 - p(c | a))
p = p(a) p(c | a)(1 - p(e | c))
= p(a) p(c | a) p(e | c)
These equations follow from basic laws of probability; p4, for instance, is the
product of the probabilities of arrest, conviction given arrest, and execution
given conviction (outcome 4). The number U given by U = U p + U p + U p + U p is
a measure of the “average” unhappiness that commission of the murder will bring
to its perpetrator, since it weights the unhappiness associated with each of the
four outcomes by the probability that outcome occurs.
(Source: Barnett 1978, p.292-293 and 302-303)
following arrest, and being executed following conviction. For example, if the
risk of arrest, conviction or execution
is increased, the potential murderer’s
unhappiness will also increase.
A rational offender would want to minimize unhappiness — he or she is therefore
likely to be deterred by the increased risks of law enforcement, including the
death penalty. Using this basic framework, Ehrlich creates a mathematical form
(called the ‘murder supply function’) that expresses the murder rate in terms of
these punishment-risk variables as well as other variables that may affect the
murder rate. Because of the technical complexity of the material, this bulletin
will not elaborate on the mathematical form and its transformation, although
they form the basis of much subsequent debate on the validity of Ehrlich’s
analysis. Interested readers should consult the original sources listed among
the references.
UNDERLYING ASSUMPTIONS OF ECONOMIC MODELS
The adequacy of a model for representing a real-life situation is often
judged by the extent to which
its underlying assumptions are valid. Estimates of the deterrent effects of
capital punishment based on economic models share a number of assumptions, some
of which relate
to highly technical issues such as the mathematical form of the murder supply
function (see, for example, Dezhbakhsh, Rubin and Shepherd 2003). In this
section, we will focus on the less technical, but nevertheless important
assumptions that are relevant to these models.
First, econometric models typically assume that people are rational in their
commission of crime (usually murder) and that they respond to incentives and
disincentives in making their decision to commit or refrain from crime (Hood
2002). This assumption is often considered unrealistic, especially since murders
are often committed when the perpetrator is angry, fearful, or otherwise out of
control. There is usually little opportunity for the murderer to reflect on the
likely consequences of action.
Ehrlich, however, did not see the
emotionality of murder as a necessary barrier to deterrence: ‘There is no reason
a priori to expect that persons who hate or love others are less responsive to
changes in costs and gains associated with activities they may wish to pursue
than persons indifferent towards the well-being of others’ (Ehrlich 1975a, p.
399). Even so, he acknowledged that not all murderers respond to incentives, but
‘it is sufficient that at least some so behave’ for the theory to be useful in
explaining murder rates (ibid, p. 415). Dezhbakhsh, Rubin and Shepherd
demonstrated mathematically that inferences about deterrence are unaffected by
the inclusion of non- negligent manslaughter and non- premeditated crimes of
passion in murder statistics (2003, pp. 355-6).
The second assumption relates to the offender’s perception of the risks involved
in the crime. The model equates perceived risks with the objective risks of
apprehension,
conviction and execution (Gibbs 1977).
Given that offenders’ subjective evaluation of the risks involved may vary
according to their knowledge of the actual risks or their personality (e.g. an
optimist might underestimate their risks
of apprehension, see Barnett 1978, p. 294), such an assumption is not always
warranted. In general, it may be argued that offenders’ perceptions about the
risks of execution may be more accurate than their perceptions about the risks
of apprehension and conviction, especially if executions are widely publicized.
Finally, regression analyses generally assume that the dependent variable (here
the murder rate) is ‘caused’ by the independent variables (risk of execution,
etc). However, it is conceivable that higher murder rates can lead to tougher
law enforcement and punishment policy, and hence the causal direction is
reversed. This problem is sometimes dealt with by using a system of simultaneous
equations, or time-lagged variables (e.g. murder rates for a particular year is
used as dependent variable while the average execution
rate for earlier years is used as independent variable).
MEASUREMENT OF VARIABLES
Regardless of which approach researchers take, they are limited by the data,
both in terms of quality and in terms of availability. While the usual problems
with official crime statistics (e.g., under-reporting or discretionary
decisions regarding recording) are not regarded as serious for homicide, other
variables typically used in empirical studies of deterrence are not as easily
available or as reliable as homicide data. For example, Fox and Radelet (1989,
p. 36) pointed out that disposition data (in relation to the number of people
charged and convicted) used by Layson (1985) are ‘of such poor quality that they
are useless for research purposes’.
Ehrlich’s (1975a) model originally took into account legitimate and illegitimate
income opportunities, but these measures were not readily available, so certain
demographic variables were used as substitutes or ‘proxies’ (Dezhbakhsh, Rubin
and Shepherd 2003, p. 351).
3. RESEARCH EVIDENCE ON DETERRENT EFFECT
Table 1 summarizes the results of the 74 research projects identified in the
literature review. The projects used a variety of methodologies, covered a range
of geographical areas (mainly in the United States) and time periods. The
majority of the studies show that the use capital punishment did not
deter the commission of homicide. If we exclude the studies that used relatively
unsophisticated research designs, and only count the 61 that involved regression
or ARIMA (autoregressive integrated moving average, a statistical modelling
technique for time-series data) analysis, only 14 (23%) found evidence
consistent with a deterrent effect, while 40 (66%) concluded that there was no
deterrent effect, and the remainder (11%) were inconclusive or found
contradictory results. It is noteworthy that all but two of the studies that
reported a deterrent effect used an economic-type model, although not all
studies that used such models came to the same conclusion. Since research
studies using econometric models represent some of the ‘best’ and most
sophisticated in this area (Hood 2002, p. 226), it is important to devote the
next few sections to a more in-depth discussion of the issues raised by
the studies using economic models.
THE BEGINNING OF ECONOMIC MODELS: THE WORK OF ISAAC EHRLICH
In ‘The deterrent effect of capital punishment: A question of life and
death’, Ehrlich (1975a) developed his model of the rational would-be murderer
who weighs up the costs and benefits of committing homicide according to the
risks of arrest, conviction and execution (see Figure 1). Ehrlich’s model
predicted the murder rate (expressed
as homicides per 1,000 of the civilian population) from the three punishment-
risk variables – the probabilities of arrest, conviction, and execution – and a
number of other relevant variables: the civilian unemployment rate, the fraction
of the civilian population in the labour force, estimated real per capita
income, the fraction of the residential population aged between 14 and 24 years,
chronological time, the fraction of nonwhites in the population, the size of the
civilian population, real government expenditure (excluding defence), and real
expenditure of police lagged by one year. The model was then tested empirically
with national time-series data from the US covering the period 1933-69. Instead
of using the natural values of the data, Ehrlich worked with logarithmic values.
This is a common technique employed where relationships between variables are
not linear but take the form of a curve.
Ehrlich’s model predicted that murderers are most sensitive to changes in the
likelihood of being arrested, less sensitive to changes in the probability of
conviction, and least sensitive to changes in the probability of being executed.
This is because the latter risk variables are conditional on the earlier risk
variable(s). For example, an increase in the likelihood of arrest also increases
the overall (unconditional) probability of conviction and that of execution. A
number of empirical regressions confirmed his ‘rational murderer’ hypothesis.
The ‘partial elasticity’ of the murder rate – the percentage change in murder
rate achieved by a one per cent change in the risk of arrest – ranged between
-1.0 and -1.5. The corresponding elasticity associated with the risk of
conviction varied between -0.4 and -0.5, while that associated with the risk of
execution
varied between -0.039 and -0.068. While the figures for the risk of execution
were small, they were statistically significant, indicating that executions
exerted a deterrent effect on those contemplating homicide. Calculating a
marginal ‘trade-off’ between executions and murders using these values of
execution risk, Ehrlich tentatively estimated that ‘an additional execution per
year over the period in question may have resulted, on average, in 7 or 8 fewer
murders’ (p. 414). It is this finding that has been frequently cited in
subsequent literature and political debates. Ehrlich noted, however, that this
was an example only. Depending upon the confidence interval chosen, the figure
could be as high as 24 fewer deaths, or as low as zero (1975a, p. 414).
In addition to finding that murders could be decreased by increasing the risk of
arrest, conviction, and execution, Ehrlich’s model found other variables
associated with reductions in homicide. Reducing unemployment exerted the same
size negative effect as did raising the risk of execution (p. 410). Labour force
participation and income levels were also significantly linked with the murder
rate. Ehrlich concluded from his regression that:
Given the validity of the analysis pursued above, incarceration or execution are
not exhaustive alternatives for effectively defending against murders. Indeed,
these conventional punishments may be considered imperfect means of deterrence
relative to monetary fines and other related compensations because the high
“price” they exact from convicted offenders is not transferable to the rest of
society.
Moreover, the results of the empirical investigation indicate that the rate of
murder and other related crimes may also be reduced through increased employment
and earning opportunities. The range of effective methods for defense against
murder thus extends beyond conventional means of law enforcement and crime
prevention. (p. 416-7)
Ehrlich’s model offered qualified support for the deterrent effect of capital
punishment. However, it also indicated that increased rates of arrest and
conviction had a more powerful effect on deterring homicide, and that socio
economic factors were as influential as executions on the murder supply
function.
Ehrlich followed up his time-series analysis with a cross-sectional study
focused on just two years – 1940 and 1950 – and disaggregated the data by State,
noting which States executed offenders and which did not. This research design
was similar to work by Passell (1975) who had found evidence to support
imprisonment as a deterrent to murder but no evidence to suggest executions
deterred. The regression model used by Ehrlich differed slightly from his
earlier study, but again tried to capture a series of socio-economic variables
as well as the risk of conviction, execution, and previous time in prison (1977,
p. 750). Ehrlich reported that the findings corroborated his earlier study,
yielding consistent results that linked executions to reductions in homicide,
and also to reductions in robbery which was not subject to capital punishment
(1977, p. 778). By including a separate variable for imprisonment, and by
disaggregating executing and non-executing States, Ehrlich was able to more
precisely measure the impact of executions, estimating that among
executing States, each additional execution reduced the number of murders by
between 20 and 24 (p. 779). He also noted the ‘intriguing’ finding that
‘persistently non-executing States face substantially lower risks of
victimization through murder and related crimes than do the persistently
executing States’ (1977, p. 780), a distinction he partly attributed to ethnic
and other demographic variations, and to misguided perceptions about the risk of
execution. Ehrlich signalled the need for further research to make sense of this
finding.
CRITICISMS OF EHRLICH
Ehrlich’s (1975a; 1977) research has spawned ‘an industry of critiques’
(Ehrlich 1982, p. 125), subjecting his work to a closer scrutiny than perhaps
any other piece of work on the deterrent effect of punishment. While it is
beyond the scope of this bulletin to give an independent evaluation of the
validity of all the criticisms, we hope to guide the reader through some of the
major criticisms, partly as an illustration of the complexity of the issues, and
partly to stimulate further research and debate. As Cameron (1994, p. 209)
observes, the jury on the econometric evidence on the effects of capital
punishment is still out – Ehrlich’s results have as yet not been ‘thoroughly
discredited’ as claimed by Lampert (1983, p. 89). There is clearly room for
further research in different jurisdictions using more reliable data and
improved techniques.
Mathematical Form Subsequent studies have replicated Ehrlich’s earlier
time-series work but not always his results (Passell and Taylor 1977; Albert
1999). Bowers and Pierce (1975) managed to repeat Ehrlich’s study and obtain the
same findings. However, they drew attention to the mathematical form used by
Ehrlich and a problem with the use of logarithms (see Ehrlich 1975b for his
response and Passell and Taylor 1977 for further problems). There is no
logarithmic value for zero, so in years when the execution rate was zero (from
1964), Ehrlich substituted a value of 1. This was subsequently identified as an
important random choice. When Bowers and Pierce ran the regression model using
the data in a non- logarithmic form (i.e., using the natural values), they found
no evidence of a deterrent effect of executions. Indeed, the only statistically
significant results were positive, associating executions
with high homicide rates. Barnett (1978, p. 298) suggested that Bowers and
Pierce might have ‘exaggerated the weaknesses of Ehrlich’s model relative to
others when p(e|c) is small’. In his view, Bowers and Pierce’s linear form has
its own problems.
Passell and Taylor (1977) also
re-examined Ehrlich’s time series model, finding it sensitive to the choice of
mathematical form and the explanatory variables included. Employing an
alternative form, they found no evidence to support deterrence. What constitutes
the appropriate mathematical form
of the murder supply equation has continued to be an area of debate (Peck 1976;
Hoenack and Weiler 1980; Layson 1985; Dezhbakhsh, Rubin and Shepherd 2003).
Period Covered
In addition to questioning Ehrlich’s functional form, Bowers and Pierce (1975)
ran the original logarithmic- based analysis excluding the problematic years
when there were no executions. Again, the deterrent effect disappeared. Bowers
and Pierce concluded that Ehrlich’s analysis ‘yields evidence of a deterrent
effect only by relying on the unusual nature of the years after 1964 and on the
logarithmic transformation of the data’ (ibid, p. 206).
Sensitivity to the choice of years had been highlighted by Baldus and Cole
(1975) who found that, depending on their choice of time period, the model could
be made to generate a positive association between risk of execution
and the homicide rate. Klein, Forst and Filatov (1978) produced an insignificant
negative coefficient by terminating the data in 1962. Ehrlich’s model was not
robust to changes in selection of years.
Another related issue arose for the time series analysis. Researchers found
reason to question the assumption that there was a constant relationship over
time between the predictor variables and the homicide rate. For example, in the
United States, unemployment rate may have a declining impact on homicide between
1933 and 1969 since ‘social legislation and the growth of union power reduced
considerably the financial hardships of unemployment’ (Barnett 1978, pp. 294-5).
Fox and
Radelet (1989) also note that the factors and conditions underlying homicide
trends are many and diverse, with those influencing the homicide rate in the
1930s different from those influencing the homicide rate in the 1970s. It is
therefore not reasonable to assume that the same set of variables would exert
the same influence on homicide rate during these decades.
Omitted Variables
The model was also criticized for omitting variables that may potentially
influence homicide rates; these include: mean sentence length of those convicted
of murder but not executed (Bowers and Pierce 1975); levels of migration into
urban centres, the extent of weapon ownership, levels of violent property crime
(Baldus and Cole 1975); racial tensions, changes in length of prison sentences,
changing aspirations and perceptions of relative deprivation (Passell and Taylor
1977).
Data Problems
Ehrlich (1975a) had used national time-series figures from the FBI for
homicides, arrests and convictions. Three problems arose from this.
Firstly, these had been generated by the Uniform Crime Reporting Scheme
which, in its early years, was considered
an unreliable source as it was voluntary and a large number of agencies did
not comply (Bowers and Pierce 1975, Peck 1976, Cantor and Cohen 1980). Homicide
figures were subsequently readjusted by the FBI on the basis of current data and
these were employed by Ehrlich. Low-level reporting was at its worst with regard
to arrests and convictions. These data were collected from ‘such small and
unrepresentative samples of law enforcement agencies’ that it was not possible
to even attempt a re-estimation of the actual figures (Bowers and Pierce 1975,
p. 190).
It was not until 1960-61 that the number of agencies reporting arrests and
convictions increased significantly.
Problems with arrest and conviction figures adversely affect all punishment
variables, as execution-risk is conditional on arrest and conviction.
Secondly, general homicide rates included less rational offenders, for example,
domestic and non-felonious murderers, and might therefore obscure the effect of
executions on rational thinkers (Cochran, Chamlin and Seth 1994).
Thirdly, some scholars have argued that there are problems with using national
statistics. Aggregated data can obscure the real relationship between homicide
and punishment, and create problems for causal inference — to conclude that
executions deter homicides, the drop in homicide rate should occur in the same
jurisdiction as the executions.
The alternative approach was to use cross-sectional data (Ehrlich 1977). This
enabled comparison across and between jurisdictions. Cross-sectional data have
the disadvantage of limiting the number of cases to the number of units of
analysis (e.g. States in the case of Ehrlich’s work, or counties in some
subsequent studies). Further, the approach suffers from ‘unobserved
heterogeneity’; that is, because the data deal with a given place and time,
unusual conditions specific to that place and time may not be apparent
(Dezhbakhsh, Rubin and Shepherd 2003).
Ceteris Paribus
Ehrlich has emphasized that the execution-murder trade-off estimate was subject
to the conditions that all other factors were held constant: ‘The
actual tradeoffs between executions and murders thus depend partly upon the
ability of law enforcement agencies to control simultaneously the values of
all the parameters characterizing law enforcement activity’ (Ehrlich1975a,
p. 415). In practice, it is not possible to
hold arrest and conviction probabilities constant while execution rates change.
Since the abolition of capital punishment in England and Wales in 1965, it had
been easier to secure convictions for murder, with the proportion of offenders
convicted of murder rising from 28 per cent in 1965 to 49 per cent in 1998-99
(Hood 2002, p. 223. For the US see Glaser 1979). Wolpin’s (1978) findings for
England
and Wales indicated that by far the largest reduction in homicide was not
brought about by executions, but by an increase in the proportion of homicides
cleared as murder (rather than manslaughter). This was so in Ehrlich’s (1975a)
formulation in which changes in the probability of conviction exert a larger
influence than equivalent changes in the risk of execution.
THE CASE FOR DETERRENCE
Different forms of multivariate analysis, some with and some without economic
modelling, have continued to be employed in an attempt to reach a definitive
answer regarding the deterrent effect of capital punishment. Primarily, the case
for executions deterring further offences is made by studies which adopt
econometric models of analysis. These research papers have become highly
technical, typically identifying problems with previous studies before positing
a new technique or modified model. The following will sketch out some of the
broad arguments and approaches; more detailed summaries can be found in Freeman
(1993), Cameron (1994), and Avio (1998).
Economic studies which found evidence consistent with a deterrent effect, and
which have not already been mentioned include: Yunker (1976), Cloninger (1977,
1987, 1992), Cloninger and Marchesini
(2001), Layson (1985, 1986),
Chressanthis (1989), and Dezhbakhsh, Rubin and Shepherd (2003).
Using annual US national data from 1933 to 1972, Yunker (1976) tested a model
which assumed that executions are positively related to the current homicide
rate, and the homicide rate is inversely related to the past level of
executions. His execution-murder trade-off predicted that one execution would
deter 156 murders (p. 381).
For a critique of this remarkable finding, see Fox (1977) who demonstrated
the serious methodological flaws in Yunker’s analysis.
Cloninger (1977) carried out a multiple regression analysis on cross-sectional
data from 48 US States for 1960, finding results consistent with deterrence
theory. His later paper (Cloninger 1987) rectified some technical errors in the
original study and found stronger support for deterrence. In 1992, he conducted
a new study using FBI crime data for each US State and the District of Columbia
during 1983-1988. Results of this second analysis were consistent with the
deterrence hypothesis: ‘both the relative risk and residual risk of homicide is
significantly reduced in the presence of executions’ (Cloninger 1992).
A similar approach was adopted by Cloninger and Marchesini (2001) when studying
homicides in Texas. Between 1996 and 1997, the number of executions in Texas
each month varied substantially. As a result of a Court of Criminal Appeal
decision to stay an execution, only three prisoners were executed in 1996. Once
the Court had lifted the stay, the number executed increased to 37 prisoners in
1997.
Using FBI data for the years 1989-1997, the researchers were able to calculate
‘expected values’ for homicides during 1996-1997. These expected values were
then compared with the actual numbers of homicide cases. Since the number of
homicides in 1996 was greater than expected, and in 1997 fewer than expected,
the researchers concluded that ‘significant changes in the number of homicides
appear associated with sudden changes in the number of executions in a manner
consistent with the deterrence hypothesis’ (Cloninger and Marchesini 2001, p.
576).
In addition to his work on Canada mentioned earlier, Layson (1985) attempted to
correct for faults in Ehrlich’s work and also extended the analysis up to 1977.
He employed an alternative data source (vital statistics). Testing for
variations over time, using different explanatory variables, and a variety of
mathematical forms, Layson found ‘solid support’ for a powerful deterrent effect
associated with increases in probabilities of arrest, conviction and execution.
He calculated a trade-off between executions and murders of 18.5 lives, plus or
minus 10 (p. 80). Layson (1986) confirmed that similar findings could be
achieved with the FBI data on homicides used by Ehrlich by omitting the first
few years (1934-1937).
Chressanthis (1989) examined the relationship between murder and
non-negligent manslaughter and capital punishment in the US for the period
1965-1985. The analysis found
support for a deterrent effect of capital punishment. It also found that changes
in law enforcement, judicial, demographic, and economic control variables were
significant and in line with the economic model of criminal behaviour.
The most recent econometric study is that of Dezhbakhsh, Rubin and
Shepherd (2003). They used a system of simultaneous equations and panel data
from 3,054 US counties over the years 1977-1996. They include in
their model control variables such as criminal justice expenditures, political
pressure to get ‘tough on crime’, rates of other crimes, economic and
demographic variables, and the rate of gun ownership. The results show support
for a strong deterrent effect. Calculating a trade-off for the US in
1996, they estimated that one execution resulted in 18 fewer murders, with a
margin of error of 10.
Dezhbakhsh, Rubin and Shepherd (2003) tested the robustness of their results
with regard to variations in aggregation level, mathematical form, sampling
period, and ways of modelling death penalty laws and the probability
of execution. They concluded that their results were not sensitive to
differences in model specifications. However, it is worth noting that this still
does not mean universal support for the deterrence hypothesis: of the 55 models
analysed, the estimated coefficient of the probability of execution was negative
and statistically significant in 49, negative but insignificant in four, and
positive in two (one of which is insignificant, the significance test of the
other was not shown). Note also that two of 37 significant results in the
robustness check were significant only at the 90 per cent confidence level (see
Dezhbakhsh, Rubin and Shepherd 2003: Table 5).
While the work of Dezhbakhsh, Rubin and Shepherd (2003) is too recent for
published rejoinders, this is not so with the other studies (e.g. Fox 1977 on
Yunker 1976). Cover and Thistle (1988) tested the time-series properties of US
homicide rate and found that the data violated some of the basic assumptions of
regression analysis. When they reanalysed Layson’s (1985) data using different
methods to get around this problem, they obtained a mixture of insignificant and
significant results.
They concluded that the results are sensitive to the way the probabilities of
arrest, conviction and execution are defined. In addition, Fox and Radelet
(1989) criticized Layson (1985) for failing to adequately account for changes
over time in the underlying relationships between variables.
Public Awareness
If executions exert a general deterrent effect on homicide one would expect more
publicized executions to exert a bigger deterrent effect. Using a published set
of weekly homicide statistics for London from 1858 to 1921, and a standard
casebook of ‘notorious murderers’ to produce a list of widely publicized English
executions, Phillips (1980) found that, on average, homicides decreased by 35.7
per cent during the two weeks immediately following a publicized execution. The
more publicity devoted to the execution, the more homicides decreased
thereafter. This effect is only short-term, as the number of homicides rose
again within five to six weeks after the execution.
Stack (1987) examined publicized execution news stories in the US during 1950-80
and found an inverse relationship between publicized executions and homicide. He
estimated that, on average, the months with highly publicized stories of
executions had 30 fewer homicides than those without such stories. A review of
this work by Bailey and Peterson (1989) identified shortcomings which, when
corrected for, indicated a very limited correlation between publicized
executions and lower homicide rates which evaporated over the following months.
Further work by Stack (1993) on Georgia failed to repeat the original result.
Monthly data were used with the outcome that a publicized execution was
associated with an increase of 2.6 homicides, or a 6.8 per cent increase
in the month of the publicized execution.
The results provided no support for deterrence theory. However, when Stack
(1998) examined California for 1946 1955, the deterrent effect was again found.
Using monthly data on publicized executions in California, Stack found that a
publicized execution was associated with a decrease of 2.6 homicides, or a 12.7
per cent decrease, in the month of the publicized execution. These findings are
inconsistent with Grogger’s (1990) study of California
for the later period 1960-1963. Using daily homicide data and a Poisson
regression model, Grogger found no evidence to support the short-term deterrent
effect of executions.
Bailey’s (1998) research on Oklahoma considered print media attention to
executions along with the frequency of executions and other socio-demographic
variables in explaining various types of homicides. The regression analysis
employed weekly data for the period 1989-91. Instead of a deterrent effect,
Bailey found that media coverage of executions was accompanied by an overall
increase in ten categories of homicide. One exception to this pattern was the
decrease of non-felony killings involving strangers, which occurred for two
weeks after the media coverage.
THE CASE AGAINST DETERRENCE
As mentioned earlier, the majority of the better designed research studies
presented in Table 1 were not able to demonstrate that capital punishment had a
deterrent effect on homicide. This is consistent with the opinions of eight out
of ten experts (67 present and former presidents of the top US academic
societies of criminology)
surveyed in the mid 1990s (Radelet and Akers 1996). The experts based their
opinion on ‘their knowledge of the literature and research in criminology’
(ibid, p. 7).
Table 1 gives a summary of the research studies that found no deterrent effect
(as indicated by a minus sign in the last column); it provides for each study
the date of publication, the geographical area covered, the time period
examined, the type of crime focused on, the methodology used and the final
conclusion. We will not attempt to summarize each study further, but will make
some general points about the range of methods employed. Note, however, that
some of the studies are replications or extensions of each other, based on
overlapping sets of data, rather than totally independent projects. For example,
Bailey, working alone or with Peterson, was responsible for 22 of the published
works cited in Table 1; while the time periods varied, fourteen of the studies
examined the US as a whole or a large number of States,
while eight focused on an individual State or city. Except for two on rape
(Bailey 1976b, 1977a) and one on
non-capital felonies (Bailey 1991), these studies consistently found no evidence
that capital punishment had a deterrent effect on homicide.
Many of these studies have used research designs similar to those discussed
above in which evidence of deterrence was found: multivariate
regression analysis using time series data (e.g. Stack 1993, Decker and Kohfeld
1984), others using cross- sectional data (e.g. Boyes and McPheters 1977, Black
and Orsagh 1978), or a combination of both (e.g. Albert 1999, Knorr 1979, Rahav
1983). Some studies have been careful to distinguish between different
categories of homicide (e.g. Cochran and Chamlin 2000, Thomson 1999, Sorensen,
Wrinkle, Brewer, and Marquart 1999, Cochran, Chamlin and Seth 1994),
and different categories of offenders (Bailey and Peterson 1999, Stack 1995),
highlighting problems with the generalisability of deterrent findings. On
occasions, crimes other than homicide have been the focus (e.g. rape, Bailey
1977a) or specific types of homicide (e.g. police killings, Bailey and Peterson
1994). The choice of variables fed into these models can differ, including the
length of imprisonment (Bailey 1980a),
the celerity of the death penalty (Bailey 1980b), and gun ownership (Kleck
1979), to name but three.
Other related methods have also been employed. Archer, Gartner and Beittel
(1983) did a cross-national study of trends in homicides following the abolition
of capital punishment, finding that, more often than not, absolute numbers of
murders fell. Forst (1983) did a similar study of US States, examining if
homicide rates rose most in States with the greatest decline in the use of
capital punishment. Forst found no perceptible impact of the death penalty on
homicide rates. A related approach was adopted by Cheatwood (1993; the same
study was reported in Harries and Cheatwood 1997) who analysed how differences
in violent crime rates related to the practice of capital punishment in
different US counties using ‘pairs’. In order to enhance comparability but also
capture differences in punishment regimes, Cheatwood selected the 293 pairs of
contiguous counties which crossed a State line and therefore jurisdictions.
Differences between violent crime rates
were calculated for each pair and fed into a regression analysis as the
dependent variable. Information on social, demographic and economic variables
known to influence violent crime rates was also entered, and for the two States
in each matched pair, capital punishment was measured in three ways: the
existence of capital statutes, numbers executed since 1976, and numbers
currently on death row.
The resulting analysis offered no
support for deterrence theory. The capital punishment variables did not have any
significant effect on the level of violent crime; and what effect they did have
was positive, not negative.
Cross-national studies such as Archer, Gartner and Beittel (1983) draw attention
to the paucity of research into capital punishment in countries outside the US,
a problem which will remain a major barrier to informing public debate. What
governs crime rates in one country will not necessarily be universal. Capital
punishment in Australia is little researched: homicide rates are lower, and the
death penalty has not operated
in any State since 1966. The little work that has been undertaken found no
evidence of deterrence. Barber and Wilson (1968) undertook a study of Queensland
data constructing a 5-year interval time-series over half a century, comparing
conviction rates for manslaughter (non-capital) with murder (capital until
1922). For the majority of five-year periods the conviction rate for
manslaughter was higher than for murder, indicating juries’ reluctance to
convict in capital cases. Murder rates fell from 1911, a trend not halted by the
abolition of capital punishment in Queensland in 1922, when it was replaced by a
mandatory sentence of life imprisonment. Their findings fail to support a
deterrent effect, and suggest that harsh penalties promote discretion and
lenience in practice.
Perhaps one of the most interesting approaches was adopted by Marquart and
Sorensen (1997, originally published in 1989) who effectively undertook a
counter-factual analysis of capital punishment when the opportunity arose to
conduct a 15-year follow-up study of commuted capital offenders
in the US, asking what threat such offenders posed to society. In 1972, 558
capital offenders had their sentences commuted to terms of imprisonment, with
239 of the inmates being released into the community on parole during the course
of the study. The project examined both prison and release behaviour. Only one
offender committed a second homicide. There were few recorded cases of
institutional misconduct; of those on parole, 12 per cent committed new
felonies, and a further nine per cent violated their parole and returned to
prison. Seventy-nine percent had no further convictions.
Marquart and Sorensen found that most
capital offenders did not engage in violent behaviour and did not represent a
significant threat to society.
What Marquart and Sorensen’s (1997) research highlights is the need to wed
research questions and methodologies appropriately. While regression analysis,
for example, is an excellent technique for assessing association between
variables, it cannot measure the direction of causation: the working hypothesis
determines this for a specific model, but cannot prove it.
If the question is about the rationality of offenders, there may be more direct
ways of penetrating the individual
decision-making process. Psychologists in particular have begun to explore
individual-level causes of crime: criminogenic needs, the influence of violence
on television, substance abuse etc. The debate over whether capital punishment
exerts a deterrent effect
on would-be offenders has been intractable, with no definitive answers. Perhaps
new methodologies need to be developed and applied before a resolution will be
found.
UNINTENDED CONSEQUENCES
An argument is mounted in a number of the studies cited for what is termed
a ‘brutalization effect’ (see, for example, Bailey 1983,1998; Bowers, Pierce and
McDevitt 1984; Harries and Cheatwood 1997). While deterrence is hypothesized as
a negative relationship between executions and homicides (executions go up,
homicides go down), brutalization is the reverse, a positive relationship
(executions go up, homicides go up). As the name suggests, in this model
citizens are ‘brutalized’ when the state sanctions death as punishment, becoming
inured to acts of violence. The state is seen
as both legitimatizing violence as a
solution to problems, and as devaluing human life. This has been an enduring
argument against the use of capital punishment since the 18th century.
Cochran and Chamlin’s research on California suggests that the 1992 execution of
Harris after a 25-year moratorium ‘may have produced two simultaneous but
opposing effects: a deterrent effect on non stranger felony-murders and a
brutalization effect on argument-based stranger homicides’ (2000, p. 700).
Another unintended consequence is that capital punishment may be
applied differentially on racial grounds. Paternoster’s (1983;1984) research on
prosecutorial discretion in requesting the death penalty in South Carolina found
that the race of the victim had a strong influence on this decision, even when
legally relevant variables have been controlled for. In particular, ‘black
killers of whites were more likely and black killers of black less likely to
have the death penalty requested’ (Paternoster 1984, pp. 466-7).
4. CONCLUSION
The efficacy of capital punishment as a deterrent against crime, as this
review of the literature shows, is still a vexed issue among researchers almost
thirty years after the publication of Ehrlich’s (1975a) econometric model. The
weight of the research evidence, covering different jurisdictions at different
time periods, still favours the ‘no
deterrence’ conclusion. Most of
these research studies, however, have not been subjected to the kind of critical
scrutiny that Ehrlich’s results have been subjected to. Recent research
that supported the deterrence hypothesis (e.g. Dezhbakhsh, Rubin and Shepherd
2003) is bound to revive interest in the capital punishment debate. If the
debate since the late 1970s is any guide, the published literature is likely to
become polarized and increasingly inaccessible to all but the most technically
competent readers, while policy advocates will continue to invoke evidence
selectively to support their positions.
It is important for those who believe in the value of research for informing
policy and clarifying issues to understand
the nature and limitations of social research. Given that it is ethically and
politically indefensible to conduct randomised experiments to test the
effectiveness of capital punishment as a deterrent, there are only a limited
range of methods researchers can use to analyse this issue. These methods have
all been tried in the literature reviewed in this bulletin, but they did not
lead to consistent findings.
Researchers must now look for reasons behind this divergence. However, it is in
the nature of research that theories and hypotheses can be tested but the
results do not constitute a definitive ‘proof’ of any theory. What statistical
analysis does is produce evidence that can be said to be consistent, or
inconsistent, with a given model or theory. All such testing is limited by the
data, the research design and statistical inference. If they had yielded a
consistent set of conclusions, researchers would have more confidence that the
results are invariant under different conditions and not sensitive to variations
in research methods.
We agree with Zimring and Hawkins (1986) that the use of capital punishment
should be a matter for political and moral choice, rather than based simply on
its efficacy as a deterrent against crime. While policy making is in the domain
of democratic processes and the political use of knowledge often an inevitable
part of that process, researchers can be drawn into the politics simply by doing
their job. Despite Ehrlich’s disclaimer that he had never advocated the use of
capital punishment (1975b, p. 227), his repeated statement that ‘the efficacy
and desirability of capital punishment are separate issues’ (Ehrlich 1982, p.
137) and that he was more concerned with establishing an
economic model of general deterrence
than focusing on capital punishment (Ehrlich 1982, p. 124), it will not be
forgotten that his findings were presented by the US Solicitor General in the
Supreme Court as an argument
to justify the constitutionality of the death penalty and hence its return (Baldus
and Cole 1975, p. 170).
Capital punishment, as Ehrlich (1975a) rightly points out, is ‘a question of
life and death’. Such questions require conclusive evidence which, as this
review of the literature shows, three decades of deterrence research has failed
to deliver.
5. ACKNOWLEDGMENT
The authors would like to thank Elizabeth Maloney for her valuable research
assistance, and Don Weatherburn for his comments on an earlier draft of this
bulletin. The opinions expressed do not represent the views of the NSW Bureau of
Crime Statistics and Research.
6. REFERENCES
Adeyemi, A.A. 1987, ‘Death Penalty: Criminological Perspectives
The Nigerian Situation’, Revue Internationale de Droit Pénal, vol. 58,
pp. 485-502.
Albert, C. 1999, ‘Challenging Deterrence: New Insights on Capital Punishment
Derived from Panel Data’, University of Pittsburgh Law Review, vol. 60, no. 2,
pp. 321-371.
Archer, D., Gartner, R. & Beittel, M. 1983, ‘Homicide and the Death Penalty:
A Cross-National Test of a Deterrence Hypothesis’, The Journal of Criminal Law
and Criminology, pp. 991-1013.
Avio, K. 1979, ‘Capital Punishment in Canada: A Time-Series Analysis of the
Deterrent Hypothesis’, The Canadian Journal of Economics, vol. 12, no. 44,
pp. 647-676.
Avio, K. 1998, ‘Capital Punishment’ in
P. Newman (ed.), The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law,
Macmillan, London.
Bailey, V. 2000, ‘The Shadow of the Gallows: The Death Penalty and the British
Labour Government, 1945-51’, Law and History Review, vol. 18, no. 2,
pp. 305-49.
Bailey, W. C. 1976a, ‘Murder and Capital Punishment: Some Further Evidence’, in
Bedau, H. A. and Pierce, C. M. (eds) Capital Punishment in the United States,
AMS Press, New York, pp. 314-335.
Bailey, W. C. 1976b, ‘Rape and the Death Penalty: A Neglected Area of Deterrence
Research’, in Bedau, H. A. and Pierce, C. M. (eds) Capital Punishment in the
United States, AMS Press, New York, pp. 336-358.
Bailey, W. C. 1977a, ‘Deterrence and the Violent Sex Offender: Imprisonment vs.
the Death Penalty’, Journal ofBehavioral Economics, vol. 6, pp. 107-145.
Bailey, W. C. 1977b, ‘Imprisonment v. the Death Penalty as a Deterrent to
Murder’, Law and Human Behavior, vol. 1, no. 3,
pp. 239-260.
Bailey, W. C. 1978a, ‘The Deterrent Effect of the Death Penalty for Murder in
California’, Southern California Law
Review, vol. 52, pp. 743-765.
Bailey, W. C. 1978b, ‘Deterrence and the Death Penalty for Murder in Utah: A
Time-Series Analysis’, Journal of Contemporary Law, vol. 5, pp. 1-20.
Bailey, W. C. 1978c, ‘An Analysis of the Deterrent Effect of the Death Penalty
in North Carolina’, North Carolina Central Law Journal, vol. 10, pp. 29-51.
Bailey, W. C. 1979a, ‘The Deterrent Effect of the Death Penalty for Murder in
Ohio: A Time-Series Analysis’, Cleveland State Law Review, vol. 28, pp. 51-81.
Bailey, W. C. 1979b, ‘Deterrence and the Death Penalty for Murder in Oregon’,
Willamette Law Review, vol.16, pp.67-85.
Bailey, W. C. 1980a, ‘A Multivariate Cross-Sectional Analysis of the Deterrent
Effect of the Death Penalty’,
Sociology and Social Research, vol. 64, no. 2, pp. 183-207.
Bailey, W.C. 1980b, ‘Deterrence and the Celerity of the Death Penalty:
A Neglected Question in Deterrence
Research’, Social Forces, vol. 58, no. 4,
pp. 1308-1333.
Bailey, W. C. 1982, ‘Capital Punishment and Lethal Assaults Against Police’,
Criminology, vol. 19, no. 4, pp. 608-625.
Bailey, W.C. 1983, ‘Disaggregation in Deterrence and Death Penalty Research: The
Case of Murder in Chicago’, Journal of Criminal Law & Criminology, vol. 74,
pp. 827-859.
Bailey, W.C. 1984, ‘Murder and Capital Punishment in the Nation’s Capital’,
Justice Quarterly, vol. 1-2, pp. 211-223.
Bailey, W.C. 1990, ‘Murder, Capital Punishment, and Television: Execution
Publicity and Homicide Rates’,
American Sociological Review, vol. 55, no. 5, October, pp. 628-633.
Bailey, W. C. 1991 ‘The General Prevention Effect of Capital Punishment for
Non-Capital Felonies’, in Bohm, R. M (ed) The Death Penalty in America: Current
Research, Anderson Publishing Co, Cincinnati, chapter 2.
Bailey, W.C. 1998, ‘Deterrence, Brutalization and the Death Penalty: Another
Examination of Oklahoma’s Return to Capital Punishment’,
Criminology, vol. 36, no. 4, November, pp. 711-733.
Bailey, W. C. & Peterson, R. D. 1987, Police Killings and Capital Punishment:
The Post-Furman Period’, Criminology, vol. 25, no. 1, pp. 1-25.
Bailey, W. C. & Peterson, R. D. 1989, ‘Murder and Capital Punishment:
A Monthly Time-Series Analysis of Execution Publicity’, American Sociological
Review, vol. 54, no. 5,
October, pp. 722-743.
Bailey, W.C. & Peterson, R. 1994, ‘Murder, Capital Punishment, and Deterrence: A
Review of the Evidence and an Examination of Police Killings’, Journal of Social
Issues, vol. 50, no. 2, Summer, pp. 53-74.
Bailey, W.C. & Peterson, R. 1999, ‘Capital Punishment, Homicide, and Deterrence:
An Assessment of the Evidence and Extension to Female Homicide’, in Zahn, M. &
Smith, M. (eds) Homicide: A Sourcebook of Social Research, Sage Publications,
California, chapter 17, p. 257.
Baldus, D. & Cole, J. 1975, ‘A Comparison of the Work of Thorsten Sellin and
Issac Ehrlich on the Deterrent Effect of Capital Punishment’, Yale Law Journal,
vol. 85, pp. 170-186.
Barber, R.N. & Wilson, P.R. 1968, ‘Deterrent Aspect of Capital Punishment and
its Effect on Conviction Rates: The Queensland Experience’, Australian and New
Zealand Journal of Criminology, vol. 2, pp. 100-108.
Barnett, A. 1978, ‘Crime and Capital Punishment: Some Recent Studies’, Journal
of Criminal Justice, vol. 6,
pp. 291-303.
Beattie, J. M. 1986, Crime and the Courts in England, 1660-1800, Clarendon
Press, Oxford.
Black, T. & Orsagh, T. 1978, ‘New Evidence on the Efficacy of Sanctions as a
Deterrent to Homicide’, Social Science Quarterly, vol. 58, no. 4, March,
pp. 616-631.
Bowers, W. J. & Pierce, G. L., 1975, ‘The Illusion of Deterrence in Isaac
Ehrlich’s Research on Capital Punishment’, Yale Law Journal, vol. 85, pp.
187-208.
Bowers, W. J., Pierce, G. L. & McDevitt, J. 1984, Legal Homicide: Death as
Punishment in America, 1864-1982, Northeastern University Press, Boston.
Boyes, W. J. & McPheters, L. R. 1977, ‘Capital Punishment as a Deterrent to
Violent Crime: Cross-Section Evidence’, Journal of Behavioral Economics, vol. 6,
pp. 67-86.
Cameron, S. 1994, ‘A Review of the Econometric Evidence on the Effects of
Capital Punishment’, The Journal of Socio-Economics, vol. 23, no. 1/2,
pp. 197-214.
Cantor, D. & Cohen, L. E. 1980, ‘Comparing Measures of Homicide Trends:
Methodological and Substantive Differences in the Vital Statistics and Uniform
Crime Report Time-Series (1933-1975)’, Social Science Research, vol. 9, pp.
121-145.
Cheatwood, D. 1993, ‘Capital Punishment and the Deterrence of Violent Crime in
Comparable Counties’, Criminal Justice Review, vol. 18, no. 2, Autumn, pp.
165-181.
Cloninger, D. 1977, ‘Deterrence and the Death Penalty: A Cross-Sectional
Analysis’, Journal of Behavioral Economics, vol. 6, pp. 87-105.
Cloninger, D. 1987, ‘Capital Punishment and Deterrence: A Revision’, Journal of
Behavioral Economics, vol. 16, no. 4,
pp. 55-57.
Cloninger, D. 1992, ‘Capital Punishment and Deterrence: A Portfolio Approach’,
Applied Economics, vol. 24, no. 6, June,
pp. 635-646.
Cloninger, D. & Marchesini, R. 2001, ‘Execution and Deterrence: A Quasi-
Controlled Group Experiment’, Applied Economics, vol. 33, no. 5, April 15,
p.569.
Cochran, J. & Chamlin, M. 2000, ‘Deterrence and Brutalization: The Dual Effects
of Executions’, Justice Quarterly, vol. 17, no. 4, pp. 685-706.
Cochran, J., Chamlin, M. & Seth, M. 1994, ‘Deterrence or Brutalization?
An Impact Assessment of Oklahoma’s Return to Capital Punishment’,
Criminology, vol. 32, no. 1, p. 107.
Cover, J. & Thistle, P. 1988, ‘Time-Series, Homicide, and the Deterrent Effect
of Capital Punishment’, Southern
Economic Journal, vol. 54, no. 3,
January, pp. 615-622.
Chressanthis, G. A. 1989, ‘Capital Punishment and the Deterrent Effect Revisted:
Recent Time-Series Econometric Evidence’, Journal of Behavioral Economics, vol.
18, no. 2,
pp. 81-97.
Decker, S. & Kohfeld, C. 1984,
‘A Deterrence Study of the Death Penalty in Illinois, 1933-1980’, Journal of
Criminal Justice, vol. 12, pp. 367-377.
Decker, S. & Kohfeld, C. 1987,
‘An Empirical Analysis of the Effect of the Death Penalty in Missouri’, Journal
of Crime and Justice, vol. 10, no. 1,
pp. 23-46.
Decker, S. & Kohfeld, C. 1990, ‘The Deterrent Effect of Capital Punishment in
the Five Most Active Execution States: A Time-Series Analysis’, Criminal Justice
Review, vol. 15,no. 2,Autumn,pp. 173-191.
Dezhbakhsh, H., Rubin, P.H. & Shepherd,
J.M. 2003, ‘Does Capital Punishment Have a Deterrent Effect? New Evidence from
Postmoratorium Panel Data’, American Law and Economics Review, vol. 5, no. 2,
pp. 344-76.
Ehrlich, I. 1972, ‘The Deterrent Effect of Criminal Law Enforcement’, The
Journal of Legal Studies, vol. 1, pp. 259-276.
Ehrlich, I. 1973, ‘Participation in Illegitimate Activities: A Theoretical and
Empirical Investigation’, The Journal of Political Economy, vol. 81, no. 3,
May-June, pp. 521-565.
Ehrlich, I. 1975a, ‘The Deterrent Effect of Capital Punishment: A Question of
Life and Death’, The American Economic
Review, vol. 65, no. 3, June, pp. 397-417.
Ehrlich, I. 1975b, ‘Deterrence: Evidence and Inference’, Yale Law Journal, vol.
85,
pp. 209-227.
Ehrlich, I. 1977, ‘Capital Punishment and Deterrence: Some Further Thoughts and
Additional Evidence’, The Journal of Political Economy, vol. 85, no. 4, August,
pp. 741-788.
Ehrlich, I. 1982, ‘On Positive Methodology, Ethics, and Polemics in Deterrence
Research’, British Journal of Criminology, v. 22, no. 2, April, pp. 124
139.
Forst, B. 1977, ‘The Deterrent Effect of Capital Punishment: A Cross-State
Analysis of the 1960’s’, Minnesota Law Review, vol. 61, pp. 743-767.
Forst, B. 1983, ‘Capital Punishment and Deterrence: Conflicting Evidence?’,
Journal of Criminal Lawand Criminology, vol. 74, no. 3, pp. 927-942.
Fox, J. A. 1977, ‘The Identification and Estimation of Deterrence: An Evaluation
of Yunker’s Model’, Journal of Behavioral Economics, vol. 2, pp. 225-242.
Fox, J. & Radelet, M. 1989, ‘Persistent Flaws in Econometric Studies of the
Deterrent Effect of the Death Penalty’, Loyola of Los Angeles Law Review, vol.
23, pp. 29-44.
Freeman, J. A. 1993, ‘Murder and Economics: A Literature Review’, Discussion
Papers in Economics, no. 93/9, June, Department of Economics, Leicester
University, Leicester.
Garland, D. 1990, Punishment and Modern Society: A Study in Social Theory,
University of Chicago Press, Chicago.
Gatrell, V.A.C. 1994, The Hanging Tree: Execution and the English People 1770-
1868, Oxford University Press, Oxford.
Gibbs, J. 1977, ‘A Critique of the Scientific Literature on Capital Punishment
and Deterrence’, Journal of Behavioral Economics, vol. 6,
pp. 279-309.
Glaser, D. 1979, ‘Capital Punishment – Deterrent or Stimulus to Murder? Our
Unexamined Deaths and Penalties’, University of Toledo Law Review, vol. 10,
pp. 317-333.
Godfrey, M. J. and Schiraldi, V. 1998, ‘The Death Penalty May Increase Homicide
Rates’, in Schonebaum, S. E. (ed) Does Capital Punishment Deter
Crime?, Greenhaven Press, San Diego, chapter 7.
Grogger, J. 1990, ‘The Deterrent Effect of Capital Punishment: An Analysis of
Daily Homicide Counts’, Journal of the American Statistical Association, vol.
85, no. 410, June, pp. 295-303.
Harries, K. & Cheatwood, D. 1997, ‘Capital Punishment and the Deterrence of
Violent Crimes in Comparable Counties’, The Geography of Execution, Rowman &
Littlefield Publishers, London, chapter 6. See Cheatwood 1993.
Hay, D., Linebaugh, P. & Thompson, E.P. 1975, Albion’s Fatal Tree: Crime and
Society in Eighteenth-Century England, Allen Lane, London, pp. 17-63.
Hoenack, S.A., and Weiler, W.C. 1980, ‘A Structural Model of Murder Behaviour
and the Criminal Justice System’,
American Economic Review, vol. 70, no. 3, pp. 327-41.
Hood, R. 2002, ‘The Question of Deterrence’, The Death Penalty, Clarendon Press,
Oxford, Third Edition, Chapter 7.
Jones, D. J. V. 1982, Crime, Protest, Community and Police in Nineteenth-
Century Britain, Routledge and Kegan Paul, London.
King, P. 2000, Crime, Justice, and Discretion in England 1740-1820, Oxford
University Press, Oxford.
Kleck, G. 1979, ‘Capital Punishment, Gun Ownership, and Homicide’, The American
Journal of Sociology, vol. 84, no. 4, January, pp. 882-910.
Klein, L., Forst, B. & Filatov, V. 1978, ‘The Deterrent Effect of Capital
Punishment: An Assessment of the Estimates’, in Blumstein, A., Cohen, J. & Nagin,
D.
(ed) Deterrence and Incapacitation: Estimating the Effects of Criminal Sanctions
on Crime Rates, Panel on research on deterrent and incapacitation effects,
National Research Council, Washington.
Knorr, S. 1979, ‘Deterrence and the Death Penalty: A Temporal Cross- Sectional
Approach’, The Journal of
Criminal Law and Criminology, vol. 70, no. 2, pp. 235-254.
Layson, S. 1983, ‘Homicide and Deterrence: Another View of the Canadian
Time-Series Evidence’, The Canadian Journal of Economics, vol. 16, no. 1,
February, pp. 52-73.
Layson, S.K. 1985, ‘Homicide and Deterrence: A Reexamination of the United
States Time-Series Evidence’, Southern Economic Journal, vol. 52, July, pp.
70-89.
Layson, S. K. 1986, ‘United States
Time-Series Homicide Regressions with Adaptive Expectations’, Bulletin of the
New York Academy of Medicine, vol. 62, no. 5, June, pp. 589-600.
Lempert, R. 1983, ‘The Effect of Executions on Homicides: A New Look in an Old
Light’, Crime and Delinquency, vol. 29, January, pp. 88-115.
Majone, G. 1989, Evidence, Argument and Persuasion in the Policy Process, Yale
University Press, New Haven and London.
Marquart, J .W. & Sorensen, J. R. 1997, ‘A National Study of theFurman- Commuted
Inmates: Assessing the Threat to Society from Capital Offenders’, in Bedau, H. (ed)
The Death Penalty in America: Current Controversies, Oxford University Press,
Oxford.
McFarland, S. 1983, ‘Is Capital Punishment a Short-term Deterrent to Homicide? A
Study of the Effects of Four Recent American Executions’, Journal of Criminal
Law & Criminology, vol 74,
pp. 1014-1032.
McGowen, R. 1986,‘APowerful Sympathy: Terror, the Prison, and Humanitarian
Reform in Early Nineteenth-Century Britain’, The Journal of British Studies,
vol. 25, no. 3, pp.312-334.
McGowen, R. 1987, ‘The Body and Punishment in Eighteenth Century England’,
Journal of Modern History, vol. 59, pp.651-679.
National Research Council Panel on Research and Deterrent and Incapacitative
Effects 1978, Deterrence and Incapacitation: Estimating the Effects of Criminal
Sanctions on Crime Rates. [Cited in Zimring and Hawkins (1986)].
Passell, P. 1975, ‘The Deterrent Effect of the Death Penalty’, Stanford Law
Review, vol. 28, pp. 61-80.
Passell, P. & Taylor, J. 1977, ‘The Deterrent Effect of Capital Punishment:
Another View’, The American Economic Review, vol. 67, no. 3, June, pp. 445-451.
Paternoster, R. 1983, ‘Race of Victim and Location of Crime: The Decision to
Seek the Death Penalty in South Carolina’, The Journal of Criminal Law and
Criminology, vol. 74, pp. 754-785.
Paternoster, R. 1984, ‘Prosecutorial Discretion in Requesting the Death Penalty:
A Case of Victim-Based Racial Discrimination’, Law and Society
Review, vol. 18, no. 3, pp. 437-478.
Peterson, R. & Bailey, W. 1991, ‘Felony Murder and Capital Punishment:
An Examination of the Deterrence Question’, Criminology, vol. 29, no. 3,
pp. 367-395.
Peterson, R. & Bailey, W. 1988, ‘Murder and Capital Punishment in the Evolving
Context of the Post-Furman Era’, Social Forces, vol. 66, no. 3, March, pp.
774807.
Peck, J. 1976, ‘The Deterrent Effect of Capital Punishment: Ehrlich and His
Critics’, Yale Law Journal, vol. 85,
pp. 359-367.
Phillips, D. 1980, ‘The Deterrent Effect of Capital Punishment: New Evidence on
an Old Controversy’, The American Journal of Sociology, vol. 86, no. 1, July,
pp. 139-148.
Potas, I. & Walker, J. 1987, ‘Capital Punishment’, Trends and Issues in Crime
and Criminal Justice, No. 3, Australian Institute of Criminology, February.
Radelet, M. L. & Akers, R. L.1996, ‘Deterrence and the Death Penalty: The Views
of the Experts’, The Journal of Criminal Law and Criminology, vol. 87, no. 1,
pp, 1-16.
Radzinowicz, L. 1948-86, A History of the English Criminal Law and its
Administration From 1750, 5 Vols:
1 (1948) The Movement for Reform;
2 (1956) The Clash Between Private Initiative and Public Interest in the
Enforcement of the Law; 3 (1956) Cross- Currents in the Movement for the Reform
of the Police; 4 (1968) Grappling for Control; 5 (With R. Hood) (1986) The
Emergence of Penal Policy in Victorian and Edwardian England, Stevens and Sons,
London.
Rahav, G. 1983, ‘Homicide and Death Penalty: A Cross-Sectional Time-Series
Analysis’, International Journal of Comparative and Applied Criminal
Justice, vol. 7, no. 1, Spring, pp. 61-71.
Samuelson, G. 1969, ‘Why was Capital Punishment Restored in Delaware?’, The
Journal of Criminal Law, Criminology and Police Science, vol. 60, no. 2,
pp. 148-151.
Savitz, L.D. 1958, ‘A Study in Capital Punishment’, Journal of Criminal Law,
Criminology and Police Science, vol. 49,
pp. 338-341.
Schuessler, K. 1952, ‘The Deterrent Influence of the Death Penalty’, The Annals
of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, vol. 284,
pp. 54-62.
Sellin, T. 1959, The Death Penalty, A Report of the Moral Penal Code
Project of The American Law Institute, Philadelphia.
Shubert, A. 1981, ‘Private Initiative in Law Enforcement: Associations for the
Prosecution of Felons, 1744-1856’,
In V.Bailey (Ed.) Police and Punishment in Nineteenth Century Britain, London.
Snell, T.L. 2001, Capital Punishment 2000, U.S. Bureau of Justice Statistics.
Sorensen, J., Wrinkle, R., Brewer, V. & Marquart, J. 1999, ‘Capital Punishment
and Deterrence: Examining the Effect of Executions on Murder in Texas’, Crime &
Delinquency, vol. 45, no. 4, October,
pp. 481-493.
Stack, S. 1987, ‘Publicized Executions and Homicide, 1950-1980’, American
Sociological Review, vol. 52, no. 4,
August, pp. 532-540.
Stack, S. 1993, ‘Execution Publicity and Homicide in Georgia’, American Journal
of Criminal Justice, vol. 18, no. 1,
pp. 25-39.
Stack, S. 1995, ‘The Impact of Publicized Executions on Homicide’, Criminal
Justice and Behavior, vol. 22, no. 2, June, pp. 172-186.
Stack, S. 1998, ‘The Effect of Publicized Executions on Homicide in Calfornia’,
Journal of Crime and Justice, vol. 21,
pp. 1-16.
Thompson, E. P. 1975, Whigs and Hunters: The Origins of the Black Act, London.
Thomson, E. 1999, ‘Effects of an Execution on Homicides in California’, Homicide
Studies, vol. 3, no. 2, May, pp. 129-150.
Tittle, C. 1969, ‘Crime Rates and Legal Sanctions’, Social Problems, vol. 16,
pp. 409-423.
Weiss, CH. 1991, ‘Policy Research as Advocacy: Pro and Con’, Knowledge and
Policy, vol. 4, no. 1&2, pp. 37-55.
Wolpin, K. I. 1978, ‘Capital Punishment and Homicide in England: A Summary of
Results’, The American Economic
Review, vol. 68, no. 2, Papers and Proceedings of the Ninetieth Annual Meeting
of the American Economic Association, May, pp. 422-427.
Yunker, J. A. 1976, ‘Is the Death Penalty a Deterrent to Homicide? Some Time-
Series Evidence’, Journal of Behavioral Economics, vol. 5, no. 1 pp. 361-397.
Yunker, J. A. 1982, ‘Testing the Deterrent Effect of Capital Punishment: A
Reduced Form Approach’, Criminology, vol. 19, no. 4, February, pp. 626-649.
Zimring, F. & Hawkins, G. 1973, Deterrence: The Legal Threat in Crime Control,
The University of Chicago Press, Chicago.
Zimring, F. & Hawkins, G. 1986, ‘Appendix: Deterrence and the Death Penalty’,
Capital Punishment and the American Agenda, Cambridge University Press,
Cambridge.
1. 2003 Dezhbakhsh, H., Rubin, P. & Sheperd, J US – 3,054
counties 1977-1996 Homicide Panel X X X Deterrent effect, with each execution
resulting in 18 fewer murders; increase in arrest, sentencing and execution all
deter +
2. 2001 Cloninger, D. & Marchesini Texas 1996-1997 Homicide X Deterrent effect
of executions, comparing low with high execution periods +
3. 2000 Cochran, J. & Chamlin, M. California 1989-1995
(Execution 1992) Homicide: felony murders of non-stranger; argument- murder of
stranger X
A* Confirmed predictions that executions reduced felony-murders of non-
strangers, but increased argument-based murders of strangers (brutalization
effect) +/–
4. 1999 Sorensen, J., Wrinkle, R., Brewer, V. & Marquart, J. Texas 1984-1997
Homicide: general and felony murder X X X Failed to find any deterrent effect
between execution and murder rates, or between executions and felony-murder
rates –
5. 1999 Thomson, E. California Before and after 1992 execution Homicide: varied
Findings indicate that there were both short-term deterrent and long- term
brutalization effects of the execution on different types of homicide, but the
net effects included increases in overall homicides and most disaggregated types
of homicides consistent with the brutalization theory +/–
6. 1999 Albert, C., US – 50 States plus District of Columbia 1982-1994 Homicide
X X X X No evidence that executions deter homicide; coefficients are
statistically insignificant –
7. 1999 Bailey, W. C. & Peterson, R. US 1976-1991 Homicide: female offenders
different varieties X X X No evidence for deterrence; evidence for possible
brutalization effect –
8. 1998 Stack, S. California 1946-1955 Homicide X X Publicizing executions was
associated with fewer homicides (12.7% in month of execution; total decrease of
99 homicides during 1946-1955) +
9. 1998 Bailey, W. C. Oklahoma 1989-1991 Homicide X X X Support for
brutalization hypothesis; possible lagged deterrent effect for level of media
coverage for non-felony murders involving strangers –
Data Period Type Yes (+)/
Year Author location covered of crime Deterrent effect** No (–)
10. 1998 Godfrey, M.
& Schiraldi, V. California 1992-1993
before & after executions; also 1952-1967 Homicide X
No evidence of deterrence; evidence of brutalization –
11. 1997 Harries, K. & Cheatwood, D., - same as Cheatwood 1993 1,725 US
counties 1988 Violent crime X X X ‘virtually’ no evidence of deterrent effect;
positive correlation between capital punishment and level of violent crime
(consistent with brutalization) –
12. 1995 Stack, S. US 1977-1984 Homicide X X No deterrent effect for African
Americans (already outsiders); deterrent effect for Caucasians +/–
13. 1994 Bailey, W. C. & Peterson, R. US 1976-1989 Homicide – various (police
killings) X X X No consistent evidence was found that capital punishment
influenced police killings during 1976-1989; no evidence of deterrence effect –
14. 1994 Cochran, J., Chamlin, M. & Seth, M. Oklahoma 1989-1991 Homicide –
general, stranger & felony murder X
A* No evidence that Oklahoma’s reintroduction of executions produced a
statistically significant decrease in the level of criminal homicides during
1989-1991; some evidence of brutalization (increased stranger homicides) –
15. 1993 Stack, S. Georgia 1950-1965 Homicide X X No support for deterrence; a
publicized execution was found to be associated with an increase of 2.6
homicides, or 6.8%, in the month of the publicized execution. Publicized
executions were associated with an increase of 55 homicides during 1950-1965. –
16. 1992 Cloninger, D. US States plus DC 1983-1988 Homicide X X Support for
deterrent effect +
17. 1991 Peterson, R. & Bailey, W. US 1976-1987 Capital homicide X X X This
investigation found no consistent evidence that executions and the television
coverage they receive are associated significantly with rates for total, index,
or different types of felony murder –
18. 1991 Bailey, W. C. US 1950 & 1960 Non-capital felonies X X X No support for
deterrence hypothesis –
19. 1990 Grogger, J. California 1960-1963 Homicide X X X The data provides no
support for the notion that executions deter homicides in the short term –Data
Period Type Yes (+)/ Year Author location covered of crime Deterrent effect** No
(–)
20. 1990 Bailey, W. C. US
(as a whole) 1976-1987 Homicide X X X Homicide rates were not found to be
related to either the amount or the type of execution publicity over the period
–
21. 1990 Decker, S. & Kohfeld, C. Five States in US – Georgia, New York, Texas,
California, and North Carolina. 1930-1980 Homicide X X X Neither the existence
of the death penalty, its imposition, nor the level of imposition explains
significant amounts of the variation in homicide rates in 50-year period
analysed –
22. 1989 Bailey and Peterson US 1950-1980 &
1940-1986 Homicide X X X No evidence that execution publicity influenced the
rate of homicide during the 1950-1980 or 1940-1986 period. Some evidence
suggests that higher levels of execution are associated with lower murder rates
– however, the apparent deterrent effect is very slight and short term –
23. 1989 Chressanthis,
G. A. US 1965-1985 Homicide X X X Finds a deterrent effect of capital punishment
does exist +
24. 1988 Cover, J. & Thistle, P. US 1937-1977 Homicide X X Results provide mixed
support for deterrence hypothesis. +/–
25. 1988 Peterson, R. & Bailey, W. US 1973-1984 Homicide X X X X The analysis
produced no indication that the national return to capital punishment since
Furman has had a systematic downward impact on homicide –
26. 1987 Stack, S. US 1950-1980 Homicide X X X Evidence of deterrence; negative
relationship between publicized executions and homicides in short term (a
publicized execution story is associated with a drop of 30 homicides in the
month of the story); no effect for executions that were not publicized. +
27. 1987 Bailey, W. C. & Peterson, R. US 1973-1984 Lethal assaults against
police X X Present analysis lends no support to the view that the death penalty
provides a more effective deterrent to police homicides than alternative
sanctions –
28. 1987 Decker, S.
& Kohfeld, C. US –
Missouri 1933-1980 Homicide X X X No deterrent effect –
29. 1987 Adeyemi, A.A. Nigeria 1967-1985 Homicides and armed robbery X There is
no support for the efficacy of the death penalty in Nigeria. Celerity was also
examined but no valid evidence was found to exist in relation to the effect of
delays in executions on the efficacy of the death penalty. –Data Period Type Yes
(+)/Year Author location covered of crime Deterrent effect** No (–)
30. 1986 Layson, S. K. US 1934-1969 Homicide X X X Evidence consistently
supports deterrence theory in general and specific hypothesis that capital
punishment is a deterrent +
31. 1985 Layson, S.K. US 1936-1977 Homicide X X X Evidence of deterrence using
Vital Statistics rather than FBI series. Trade-off between executions and
murders of 18.5 lives, plus or minus 10 +
32. 1984 Bailey, W. C. District of Columbia 1890-1970 Murder X X X No support
for deterrence, however suggests immediate effects of executions may increase
not decrease murders. However this effect is extremely slight and short term. –
33. 1984 Bowers, Pierce & McDevitt New York State 1906-1963 Homicide X
Brutalization effect (executions associated with increased homicides) –
34. 1984 Decker, S. & Kohfeld, C. Illinois 1933-1980 Homicide X X X No evidence
for a deterrent effect for the death penalty on homicides in Illinois –
35. 1983 Layson, S. Canada 1927-1977 Homicide X X X Supports the hypothesis that
capital punishment is a deterrent +
36. 1983 Lempert, R. Same States as Sellin 1959 1920-1955 Homicide X X Using
correlations they find the data provide no reason to believe that executions
deter homicide –
37. 1983 Rahav, G. From 17 countries 1955-1972 Homicide. Larceny is used as a
comparison X X X X The analysis shows that the death penalty has a very low,
inconsistent effect upon both homicide and murder rates –
38. 1983 Bailey, W. C. US – city of Chicago, Illinois 1915-1921 Murder X X X In
line with the brutalization argument, this analysis suggests that the net effect
of executions may well have been to increase, not decrease, Chicago first-degree
murders and total criminal homicides. –
39. 1983 Archer, D., Gartner, R. & Beittel, M. From 14 countries Varies by
country; generally one year before/after abolition, five years before/ after
abolition & maximum length periods before/ after abolition Homicide X X X The
evidence fails to support, and indeed, repeatedly contradicts the proposition
that if capital punishment is a more effective deterrent than life imprisonment,
its abolition ought to be followed by homicide rate increases. –
40. 1983 McFarland, S. US Looks at weeks surrounding
4 executions
(one in 1977, two in 1979, and one in 1981) Homicide X
A* X No evidence that capital punishment has either a short-term deterrent or a
rebound effect on homicides –
41. 1983 Forst, B. US States data 1960-1970 Homicide X X X X The findings
suggest that on balance the death penalty does not have a perceptible influence
on the homicide rate. –
42. 1982 Bailey, W.C. 50 US
States 1961-1971 Lethal assaults against Police X X X Contrary to the deterrence
hypotheses, no support is found for the argument that the provision and use of
the death penalty provides an added measure of protection for the police –
43. 1982 Yunker, J. A US 1907-1979 Homicide X X X Indirect test of deterrence
hypothesis. Extrapolation of a predicted homicide rate estimated over the
capital punishment era into the postcapital punishment era suggests that the mid
1960s surge in crime is unlikely to be caused by socioeconomic factors. Author
argues that the moratorium on capital punishment may be an explanation, although
there may be other causes. +/–
44. 1980 Philips, D London 22 executions
1858-1921 Homicide X On average homicides decrease by 35.7% following a
publicized execution. The more publicity, the more homicides decrease. Capital
punishment appears to have a short-term, but not a long-term, deterrent effect
on homicides. +/–
45. 1980a Bailey, W. C. 39 US States 1910-1962
(used 28 years selected from this period) Homicide X X X Only small negative
correlations between executions and homicide rates; socio-demographic indicators
and length of imprisonment both better determinants of murder rates than
executions +/–
46. 1980b Bailey, W. C. 40 US States 1960 Homicide X X X The analysis
consistently fails to provide support for the deterrence argument for the
certainty and celerity of executions –
47. 1979b Bailey, W. C. Oregon 1918-1962 Murder X X No evidence to support the
deterrence hypothesis – execution rates and homicide rates were found to be
largely independent factors –
48. 1979a Bailey, W. C. Ohio 1910-1962 Homicide X X No evidence to support the
deterrence hypothesis. A very slight nonsignificant negative association between
certainty of execution and offence rates. Sociodemographic factors proved to be
better predictors. –
49. 1979 Avio, K. Canada 1926-1960 Murder X X X A statistically significant
independent deterrent effect of capital punishment is not found for Canada over
the period 1926-1960 in this study –
50. 1979 Kleck, G. US 1947-1973 Homicide X X X Evidence does not support death
penalty exerted any general deterrent effect on the homicide rate in the US
during period since WWII. No consistent support for brutalization effect. –
51. 1979 Knorr, S. 45 US States examined on a national, regional & State level
1940-1960
(regressions performed over sub-period 1950-1960) Homicide X X X X In none of
the equations could the death penalty be regarded as an effective deterrent –
only the probability of apprehension was found to be significant and even then
only on the State level –
52. 1978 Black, T. and Orsagh, T. 43 US States
for 1950 & 47 US States
for 1960 1950 and 1960 Homicide X X X Unable to find a consistent relationship
between sanctions and homicide, therefore no deterrent effect –
53. 1978 Wolpin, K. I. England and Wales 1929-1968 Homicide X X X Executing an
additional convicted murderer reduces the number of homicides by 4.08 potential
victims +
54. 1978a Bailey, W. C. California 1919-1962 Homicide X X No evidence that the
certainty of execution provides an effective deterrent to murder to California –
55. 1978b Bailey, W. C. Utah 1910-1962 Homicide X X No evidence that the
certainty of execution has provided an effective deterrent to murder in Utah –
56. 1978c Bailey, W. C. North Carolina 1910-1962 Homicide X X No deterrent
effect; For the years considered, changes in the certainty of execution and
homicide rates were found to be generally unrelated factors –
57. 1977a Bailey, W. C. 16 US States 1951 and 1961
58. 1977b Bailey, W. C. US States – some States were excluded from various years
due to missing data 1950 & 1960
(1920, 1930 &
1940 census years are also used as a comparison) Homicide X X The certainty of
execution and homicide rates were found to be generally unrelated. Also the
significant negative bivariate relationship between the severity of prison
sentence and homicide rates found in this and earlier studies is shown to be a
statistical artefact resulting from a failure to control for the effects of
alternative legal sanctions and sociodemographic factors –
59. 1977 Cloninger, D. (error corrected
in 1987 publication) 48 US States 1960 Homicide X X X The evidence was found to
be consistent with the deterrence hypothesis with respect to execution rates and
to a lesser extent to confinement rates +
60. 1977 Boyes, W. J. & McPheters, L.R. 47 US
States 1960 Violent crime – homicide, rape and assault X X X Overall, the
deterrent effect of capital punishment is insignificant –
61. 1977 Ehrlich, I, US States – number of States used in each regression varies
1940 and 1950 Murder & related violent crimes X X X Findings indicate a
substantial deterrent effect of punishment on murder and related violent crimes
and support the economic and econometric models used in investigations of other
crime +
62. 1977 Passell, P. & Taylor, J. US 1935-69 Homicide X X X Finds Ehrlich’s
model sensitive to functional form and choice of variables. On the basis of
Ehrlich’s research, it is prudent neither to accept nor reject the hypothesis
that capital punishment deters murder. +/–
63. 1977 Forst, B. 32 US States Change from 1960-1970 Homicide X X X Findings do
not support the hypothesis that capital punishment deters homicides. –
64. 1976 Yunker, J. A. US States 1933-1959 for
estimation of E function
1960-1972 for
estimation of HR function Homicide X X X In 1960-1972 there has been a strong
inverse association between executions and homicide rate. One execution will
deter 156 murders.
1933-1959 shows a strong positive relation between AE (aggregate executions in
past three years) but interpreted this as not causal but association +
65. 1976a Bailey, W. C. US States (42) 1967 and 1968 Murder X X X Findings are
inconsistent with deterrence theory –
66. 1976b
Bailey, W. C. US States 1933-1936
& 1944-1967 Forcible rape X X Contrary to deterrence theory, rape rates were
found to be generally higher in death penalty retentionist States for most years
compared with abolitionist States, although the differences were slight. A
cross- sectional analysis of levels of execution and rape rates revealed a
negative association between these two variable for most years, but with some
positive association in some years. A longitudinal analysis of changes in the
levels of execution and corresponding changes in rape rates within death penalty
States showed the correlation to be negative in only about half of the cases.
+/–
67. 1975 Passell, P. States in US – 41 in 1950 and
44 in 1960 1950 and 1960 Murder and non- negligent manslaughter X X X No
evidence of execution as a deterrent. Conviction rates, average prison
sentences, poverty, age, and rural-urban migration + southern states explain a
great deal of the State-to-State murder rate variations. But variations in
execution rates add no explanatory power –
68. 1975a Ehrlich, I. US 1933-1969 Homicide X X X Evidence of deterrent effect +
69. 1975 Bowers, W. & Pierce, G. US 1933-1969 Homicide X X X Fails to find
evidence supporting deterrent effect; major critique of Ehrlich –
70. 1969 Samuelson, G. Delaware – USA – CP
abolished in 1958 &
reintroduced in Dec 1961 1956-1966 Manslaughter and murder Annual rate of murder
commitments higher before and after than during abolition – CP does not serve as
a deterrent to criminal homicide –
71. 1968 Barber, R.N. & Wilson, P.R. Queensland, Australia – abolition of CP in
1922 1900-1939 Murder Murder rate in QLD fell from 28.4 per million population
in 1901 to 14.0 per million in 1931. Abolition did not cause increase in murder
rate.
CP no better deterrent than mandatory life imprisonment for murder in QLD –
72. 1959 Sellin, T. US – 5 groups of 3 contiguous States (States are matched and
at least one of three had CP) 1940-1955 Homicide X Average annual rate of
homicide bore no relationship to whether or not death was the maximum penalty
for murder –
73. 1958 Savitz, L.D. Philadelphia – four cases sentenced to death 1944,
1946, 1946,
1947 1944, 1946,
1946, 1947 First degree murder – Philadelphia police ‘murder books’ No pattern
that would indicate deterrence. There was no significant decrease or increase in
the murder rate following the imposition of the death penalty on four separate
occasions –
74. 1952 Schuessler, K. US States 1925-1949 Homicide X X Homicide rate does not
drop consistently as the certainty of death –
Sweden 1754-1942 Murder and penalty increases; geographic correlations between
risk of execution
Netherlands 1850-1927 attempted and homicide rate is not statistically
significant; homicide rate and
murder execution risk as time series move independent of one another
** Summaries of findings may contain verbatim text from the cited papers – for
simplicity of presentation, quotation marks will not be used to indicate these
texts. A* Autoregressive integrated moving average (ARIMA) analysis
| |
|