Australia's Experience with Financial Deregulation
Ric Battellino [1]
Deputy Governor, RBA
Address to China Australia Governance Program,
Melbourne – 16 July 2007
PDF
version 109KB
Introduction
It is a great pleasure to be able to share with you some of Australia's
experiences with financial deregulation. Even though the process of financial
deregulation in Australia was largely completed 20 years ago, many of the
lessons learnt from that experience remain relevant today. I think they are
particularly relevant for today's seminar because Australia's financial controls
prior to deregulation had much in common with the financial controls we see in
China today.
I should also mention that while financial deregulation in Australia was largely
completed 20 years ago, the reform process did not end there. In the period
since, there have continued to be changes to the laws under which the financial
sector operates, to ensure that the sector remains dynamic and competitive.
The
Australian System Pre-deregulation
Financial deregulation in Australia began in the early 1970s. At that time,
there were wide-ranging controls on the financial system. The aims of those
controls were to:
·
provide the authorities with the mechanism to manage the monetary side of
the economy;
·
create a captive market for government securities, so as to allow the
Government to fund itself;
·
limit the risks that banks could take – i.e. they were a de facto form of
prudential supervision;
·
allocate credit to areas of the economy that authorities thought should get
priority. Housing and farming were particularly favoured; and
·
maintain a stable exchange rate and prevent the flow of domestic savings
offshore.
The controls that were put in place to further these objectives were extensive.
Listing them all could easily fill up the whole time allocated to me, so let me
cut them down to their essential elements.
1.
The interest rates that banks
could charge on loans and pay on deposits were controlled, and generally did
not vary much. This effectively prevented banks from managing or, more
specifically, expanding their balance sheets.
2.
Banks were subject to reserve ratios and liquidity ratios. These
ratios were used by the authorities to control the second-round effects on
bank balance sheets of exogenous flows of liquidity from either the balance
of payments or fiscal policy.
3.
Banks were subject to directives on the overall quantity of loans and
at times there was moral suasion in relation to the industries to which
loans should or should not be made.
4.
Institutions were specialised:
trading banks lent to businesses;
savings banks lent to households, almost entirely for housing; and finance
companies lent for more risky property loans and consumer credit.
5.
All transactions in foreign exchange were closely controlled,
particularly capital transactions, which were individually approved.
Australians by and large were not allowed to make portfolio investments
offshore, mainly because the authorities wanted to preserve domestic savings
for domestic investment.
6.
The exchange rate was managed
very tightly. Australia did not join the many other developed economies that
moved to a floating exchange rate after the breakdown of the Bretton Woods
arrangements in the early 1970s.
Reasons
for Change
Why did Australia move away from this system? I think there are four broad
reasons.
·
First, being heavily focused on banks, the controls were weakening the
position of banks and hampering their ability to respond to customer needs.
Banks were rapidly losing market
share in the financial system; by the early 1980s their share had fallen to
40 per cent, compared with 70 per cent in the early 1950s.
·
Second, the controls were becoming ineffective, as new, unregulated,
intermediaries sprung up to provide finance.
·
Third, the increase in international
capital flows following the breakdown of the Bretton Woods arrangements
began to put pressure on the Australian dollar exchange rate. The
authorities could stabilise the exchange rate only by engaging in large
foreign exchange transactions, which in turn made it difficult to manage
domestic liquidity and domestic financial conditions more generally.
·
Fourth, the financial system was quite inefficient, with wide interest
spreads, little innovation and many creditworthy potential borrowers unable
to get access to credit.
The Start
of the Deregulation Process
By the time I joined the Reserve Bank in the early 1970s, there was already an
active internal debate about the need for change. But there was also a fear that
change could lead to a loss of control over the financial system. In any event,
the power to make changes did not rest solely with the Bank; many of the
financial controls were embedded in legislation and therefore the Treasury and
the Government needed to be convinced before any changes could be made.
The early moves towards deregulation were tentative. There was an alternative
school of thought that the problems with the controls in place could be overcome
simply by extending their range and reach. For example, legislation was prepared
to extend controls to the new non-bank intermediaries which were springing up
because of the controls on banks. This legislation was never proclaimed,
however, as the intellectual drive towards deregulation eventually dominated.
One of the first major steps in the
deregulation process was the removal in 1973 of controls over the interest rates
that trading banks could pay on some wholesale deposits. This was seen as
a modest, cautious step to allow banks a degree of freedom to compete.
This ended up having far-reaching consequences. It led to a sequence of changes,
each one begetting the next, until 13 years later -
-
virtually all controls on banks had been removed,
-
foreign banks had been allowed to enter the market; and
-
the exchange rate had been floated.
The key changes in this sequence were as follows:
1.
The removal of interest rate
controls on banks. As noted, this began in 1973 and was designed to
allow banks to compete more effectively for deposits and loans. It did this,
but it also had the unintended consequence of reducing the effectiveness of
the reserve and liquidity ratios on banks. This was because banks could now
counter a change in the reserve ratio by adjusting their deposit interest
rates to compete more aggressively for funds. These funds often came from
foreign capital inflows, as the relatively fixed exchange rate necessitated
intervention by the Reserve Bank, which added to bank liquidity. The Reserve
Bank then had to rely on market operations in government securities to
control liquidity, but the effectiveness of these was limited because
interest rates on government securities were generally set too low by the
authorities, making it difficult to sell the required amount of securities.
2.
To address this latter problem, further reforms were introduced to
free up interest rates on government securities. Instead of the authorities
setting these interest rates, securities were issued at tender, and the
market set the interest rate. Tenders were adopted for Treasury notes in
1979 and Treasury bonds in 1982. This had the desired effect of allowing
both the Government, through primary issue, and the Reserve Bank, through
operations in the secondary market, to sell the required amount of bonds.
But this still did not give the authorities effective monetary control, as
evidenced by the limited success in achieving the monetary targets that were
in place at that time. The relatively fixed exchange rate remained a weak
point in the monetary control process, as attempts by the Reserve Bank to
change monetary conditions were significantly offset by private capital
flows.
3.
This weakness was not
overcome until the exchange rate was floated in 1983. The authorities
had been gradually moving to introduce greater flexibility in the exchange
rate since 1971, but none of the exchange rate regimes introduced over the
ensuing decade or so provided sufficient flexibility to ensure that domestic
monetary policy was not overwhelmed by foreign capital flows. The float
changed this. It allowed the exchange rate to vary with the forces of supply
and demand and eliminated the need for the Reserve Bank to clear the foreign
exchange market. This severed the influence of foreign capital flows on
domestic liquidity and gave the central bank the power to control domestic
financial conditions. It allowed the implementation of monetary policy to
move away from the use of reserve and liquidity ratios on banks to the use
of market operations to influence short-term market interest rates and,
through that channel, the interest rates that all lenders charged on loans.
This resulted in monetary policy working more broadly through the financial
system, rather than being focused only on banks, making it more effective
and also less distorting.
4.
The final set of measures aimed to increase competition in the
financial sector. The main reform
was to allow foreign banks to enter the Australian financial system, but
processes for establishing new domestic banks were also eased.
What
Lessons Can Be Drawn?
Let me end by drawing together some of the key points that we learnt from the
process of deregulation in Australia.
·
The first point is that it is very important to harness public and community
support for change. Even though the intellectual climate within the Reserve
Bank and other economic policy agencies was already moving in favour of
deregulation in the early 1970s,
wider community acceptance of the case for change did not come until after
the Government set up a broad-ranging inquiry, conducted by a group of
independent experts.
·
Second, the reform process can take a long time to implement because
controls are typically removed sequentially. While it is possible to take a
‘big bang’ approach and remove many regulations simultaneously, such a
process can be difficult to manage. In Australia's case, it was not regarded
as feasible to remove regulations simultaneously, mainly because of
uncertainty about the consequences. While public inquiries had mapped out a
range of reforms that needed to be introduced, the sequencing of these
reforms was determined in a pragmatic way, in response to unfolding events
and the consequences of previous reforms.
·
Third, the consequences of reforms are not always entirely predictable. Our
experience was that the removal of one set of controls often put pressure on
other controls. This meant that the reform process, once it had begun,
developed its own momentum.
·
Fourth, some of the effects of
reforms may take longer than expected to emerge. For example, one of
the predicted consequences of deregulation was an increase in the
competitiveness and efficiency of the banking sector. Yet, in the retail
lending market in Australia, interest margins remained high for about a
decade after the reforms. Part of the problem was that new banks found it
difficult to enter the retail market as they lacked the widespread branch
network of established major banks. These branch networks not only supplied
low-cost retail deposits but also provided the distribution outlet for loan
products. It was not until further financial innovation – such as the
development of securitisation markets, mortgage brokers and electronic
banking – took place that these barriers to competition were broken down.
·
Fifth, removing controls on banks
will almost certainly result in a surge in credit growth. This
reflects both demand and supply influences. A regulated financial system
often tends to result in credit rationing, so there is unsatisfied demand
for credit in the community; this is able to be met once the controls are
removed. Also, the removal of controls can result in an increase in
competitive behaviour by intermediaries as they try to increase, or even
protect, market share; the end result is an increase in the willingness to
supply credit.
·
Sixth, it is important to ensure that a sound prudential supervision
framework is developed as regulatory controls on banks are removed. Under a
regulated financial system, banks have little incentive or need to develop
their risk management skills, as interest rates and exchange rates are
relatively steady and credit rationing limits the extent to which risky
borrowers can access loans. Once regulations are removed, competition can
result in a surge in risk-taking. Domestic banks may be particularly
vulnerable as their risk management systems may be less developed than those
of foreign banks. Supervisors need to be prepared for this and need to
monitor developments in the banking system closely.
The final point I would make is that the benefits of deregulation are
broad-ranging and powerful. I would categorise these benefits into two types.
The first relate to improvements in the operation of the financial system. Once
regulations are removed, the financial sector becomes not only more efficient
but also more responsive to the financial needs of the economy. New financing
techniques and markets develop, resulting in a more diversified and resilient
financial sector.
The second set of benefits relate to improvements in monetary control. In the
Australian experience, notwithstanding some significant transitional
difficulties, the move away from using
direct controls to implement monetary policy to a system based on market
operations ultimately gave the authorities greater scope to manage the economy,
and helped pave the way for a return to economic stability.
|