Peter Mair spent decades at the Reserve Bank and
now lifts the skirt on the
latest dodgy tactics by the banking cartel and their compliant regulators.
The Reserve Bank meets the Parliamentary "Banking" Committee (EFPA) on 31
May. The discussion will probably touch only briefly on payments system
policy issues, a full year since the previous skimped discussion. Key
elements of credit-card policy are yet to be 'finally' decided by the
Reserve Bank, and then the debate will move to the courts. Rest assured
nothing is likely to be done about matters 'subjudice'. De ja vu.
An inquiry into the trade practices law is getting underway and offers hope
of stronger laws against price fixing, including by banks in respect of
their credit card and BPay schemes.
All up, the Australian community could be fairly dissatisfied with the
performance and lack of accountability of those responsible for reforming
retail banking and payment systems. In the five years since the 'Wallis'
banking inquiry, the problems in the retail payments system have generally
got worse. Insincere rhetoric has been the constant backdrop to an
interminable process of 'studies', 'consultation reports' and further
'ongoing consultations' mainly with industry executives affronted by the
intention, finally, to assert the public interest. A quite separate policy
authority could usefully specialise in retail banking issues for a few
years.
The underlying tragicomedy with credit cards is unerringly moving to the
frustration of promised reforms in the courts. At some point the Australian
community might ask that the law on trade practices be strengthened to
preclude the continued abuse of its best interests. It would be a fair
question. Hopefully that question will be put repeatedly to the ACCC
Inquiry.
One of the quaint characteristics of parliamentary committee processes is
the opening exhortation to witnesses to not mislead the Parliament. It may
be instructive for some researcher to consider answers to similar questions
in a related sequence of parliamentary committee hearings. Some clues are
given in the 'appendix'.
1. CREDIT CARDS -- A TOPICAL ISSUE
Pending a legal challenge to any decision that the Reserve Bank may make
about setting interchange fees for credit card transactions, the Reserve
Bank is momentarily sitting pretty on a document proposing effective action.
The Reserve Bank would be surprised to find itself on the front line against
the global credit card industry. The competition authorities in the UK and
Europe have left it to Australia to make the 'card' yards.
Make no mistake, the Reserve Bank consultation document, if implemented,
would rip the black heart out of credit card schemes globally -- other
countries could not ignore, and would sensibly welcome, the Australian
action. Moreover the Reserve Bank's related intention to rule out
interchange fees for debit card transactions conceptually destroys the
preferred fallback position of the retail banking industry, to abandon
credit cards once comparable interchange fees are attached to debit card
transactions.
Ignoring bygones, the Parliamentary "Banking" Committee would appropriately
congratulate the Reserve Bank on the way its consultation document proposes
dealing with interchange fees in credit card schemes -- but then quickly
move to the real issues.
(Under no circumstances should the Parliamentary Committee dwell on the
dummy passes masquerading as 'surcharging' or 'new entrants' in the RBA
consultation document. Nor should any credence be given to the tantrums put
on over recent months by either our banking industry 'leaders' and the
visiting hit men, from Visa and MasterCard acting for the global banks
milking the global community with these schemes.)
The legal challenge
Good intentions are never enough, good works are also necessary.
By now the Reserve Bank should have a view about the legal footing on which
it stands, of its chances of making stick a decision about regulating
interchange fees for credit card transactions. What does it think about the
adequacy of its enabling legislation? Views about the legal foundations for
payments system policy are about to be made clear anyway and, if they are
shaky, this opportunity for the RBA to ask the Parliament for effective
legislation should not be missed. The public will be listening for the
question and the answer. A following question might inquire, as appropriate,
why the 'alarm' was not raised previously.
The inquiry into the trade practices law will bring this issue about
ineffective trade practices law into the open. Ideally the prospective 'use'
of legal processes to defer the implementation of reforms to interchange
fees would have been headed off earlier. If the credit card matter
languishes in the courts, those effectively on trial will include the
Parliament, and its advisers that failed to put effective trade practices
law in place.
At a minimum, arrangements that fix prices should be proscribed unless they
have the prior approval of the competition policy authorities and then only
to the extent necessary to maximise the community benefit of the
arrangement.
Having made a grandstanding display of bureaucratic bravado in December 2000
to takeover the prosecution of credit card schemes, it will now be an acute
embarrassment if the RBA's payment system law is similarly exposed as
ineffective and they did not know. The irony will not be lost on Alan Fels
and the ACCC, now making a comeback after being 'benched' from the
prosecuting team.
2. BPay STINKS TOO
The re-entry of the ACCC to the debate on bank 'price-fixing' not
surprisingly concerns the banks' BPay bill payment scheme. The timing of the
re-entry suggests the ACCC is thinking the RBA is about to 'get bogged down
in the courts' with the credit card matter and exposure of BPay may usefully
underwrite a call for more effective trade practices law. It should.
BPay is more offensive than credit cards if only because it involved banks
quite recently in a plan to put in place a uniform pricing arrangement
already regarded as inappropriate. Moreover the banks developed the BPay
scheme outside the policy framework, APCA, that was put in place to protect
the community against such objectionable initiatives. The development of
BPay in 1997 confronted the authority of the Reserve Bank -- and the banks
got away with it. Wish the ACCC well.
BPay is based on the credit card network model. BPay, like credit cards, is
basically a good product except that, like credit cards, it has an
objectionable interchange fee built into the pricing contracts. It was
objectionable also that the banks developed the BPay facility to substitute
for an established service (direct debits) that was inherently better and
cheaper but not marketed effectively because it was less profitable.
Calls for the authorities to bring banks to account for their BPay scheme
repeatedly fell on deaf ears. No statistics are collected and published for
BPay transactions. It is never really mentioned. Details of the scheme are
'secret' rather than transparent. BPay has been allowed to stay and prosper
when it should have been reoriented in the public interest. As should credit
card schemes.
It would be useful for the Parliament to ask the Reserve Bank to share what
it knows about BPay and its pricing arrangements -- and then ask why nothing
has previously been said.
3. OTHER ISSUES
The 'other issues' are of course the same issue -- the ineffectiveness of
policy processes for dealing appropriately with the retail banking industry.
There is a litany of well-intentioned pontificating about what should happen
that stands in sharp contrast to the nothing-really-doing reality of not
reforming the retail banking industry -- about the inefficient, overpriced
transaction services that underwrite banks' excessive profitability (and a
quiet life at the RBA and APRA).
With the meter running at some $1 billion p.a. for the credit card rort
alone, it is far better being a banker-owner of the 'cab' than the
paying-passengers stuck at the regulatory traffic lights for the past 5
years already.
The latest recitation of this litany was in the third annual report of the
Reserve Bank Payments System Board -- released on Easter eve, some
six-months late.
On with the game
Moving beyond credit card schemes, an appropriate agenda for the 31 May
hearing would include both the contents of the third (2001) annual report of
the Reserve Bank's, Payments System Board and some policy issues not
mentioned in that report.
The general tone of this six-months-late report is laboured and tedious: it
is repetitive of issues still outstanding that should have been resolved
years ago.
Among other surprising things, there is no mention of the pre-election
posturing of the banks to 'restore free-of-charge banking transactions' to
those without the minimum deposit balances (or loans) required to be given
exemptions from paying transaction fees. No comment on how this 'free for
all' does not fit sensibly with the 'lecture' on the importance of
explicitly linking prices to costs -- and the preference for the 'needy' to
be subsidised directly by government.
The best way for the general public to be appraised of the significance of
this Payments System Board report would imagine an audience of bankers and
policy makers listening to extracts read aloud from the report. People
laughing to death (many deservedly) would be wonderfully illustrative.
The direct debit system still languishes notwithstanding that Reserve Bank
has long declared it to be the most highly efficient payment instrument.
Blissfully unknowing that the banks have no intention of making this system
work as it should, the Payments System Board wistfully "looks to financial
institutions to play their part in promoting the use of this highly
efficient payment instrument". The Board, apparently unthinkingly, "remains
committed to improving customer safeguards" as embodied in its Charter for
Direct Debit Customers that is apparently largely ignored. Spare my days.
The Payments System Board seems not to appreciate that banks developed the
BPay system to displace 'direct debits'. The apparent clarity with which the
Reserve Bank now sees how credit cards displace debit card transactions,
belies its inability to 'see' the displacment of direct debits by the much
more profitable BPay scheme. The BPay scheme also has a uniform interchange
fee underwriting its excessive profitability. There is not even the stated
intention at the Reserve Bank to 'study' the banks BPay scheme -- the mind
boggles at this intellectual inconsistency. Thankfully the ACCC now has the
BPay scheme on its 'investigative' agenda.
A little later in the report, following a '101' style lecture on the
importance of prices reflecting relative costs, it is noted that "
successive Australian governments have made a strong commitment to promoting
competition and this is echoed in the Board's mandate in the payments area".
It was once proposed that towards the mid-1980s, a room '101' might be made
available for those peddling such patently insincere dogma. The actual
results of this 'strong commitment' are there for all to see -- and the
clamour is swelling for 'two good' and 'four bad'. (Pillars, that is)
At some point the considerable distance between good intentions and the
blinding reality of inefficiency in an uncompetitive retail banking system
becomes difficult to reconcile with a supposedly sincere effort to properly
inform either Parliament or the wider community.
Further on the report repeats a conclusion of the October 2000 card
transaction study -- that "there was no convincing case for an interchange
fee in Australia's debit card payment system". Eighteen months on, one
wonders why there still is an interchange fee in Australia's debit card
payment system. The answer beggars belief. The Board wanted to "emphasise
that the initiative for reform in the debit card market is... in the hands
of industry participants": that is in the hands of those behind the current
scheme that endures against the public interest. There is little comfort in
the observation that "the Bank has now begun to work with industry
participants to consider options for change".
Having seen, with the credit card matter, the gap between the Bank 'beguning'
something and even approaching effective action, the community might
reasonably despair. The RBA inaction on BPay is similarly cautionary. Not
surprisingly, the always-objectionable VisaDebit card continues to be widely
used notwithstanding that it was eventually assessed by the Reserve Bank to
have "no place in the Australian payments system".
What is going on here?
And there are omissions. One of the more exciting current developments in
retail payments systems is the development of internet funds transfer
schemes that literally allow everyone to pay anyone, anywhere, anytime --
provided only that the payer knows the account numbers of the payee. This
system, capable of replacing the cheque, needs the well-informed
coordinating influence of industry standards and the considered official
endorsement of the monetary authorities -- I could see no mention of it.
Much the same goes for 'electronic currency' capable of substituting cheaply
and effectively for conventional currency. A commercially viable, electronic
cash scheme continues to be elusive with pilot schemes disappointing
expectations. Little wonder there was a 'tech wreck' when a 'new economy'
capacity to deliver goods and services was not matched by the capacity for
customers to pay for them using 'old economy' technology. Apparently,
nothing much is going on here either -- and this is the supposed future.
End piece
The latest 'annual' report of the Reserve Bank's Payments System Board
should be acknowledged as a final straw.
At some point the community can fairly say, enough is enough. It can
reasonably demand acceptance that the regulatory framework in place simply
is not delivering acceptable outcomes for retail payment systems. It is time
for a new start, a different approach -- more effective legislation and more
effective policy developed by a policy agency not confused by an
'obligation' to protect the banks.
Ideally a redistribution of responsibility for payments system policy would
be accompanied by tax policy reforms. The payment system should be cut off
from its dependence on the tax-avoiding bartering of 'free' transactions for
'free' deposits. The attendant cross-subsidisation of payment system costs
from the deposit and lending, intermediation operations of banks is a major
reason why the market does not work as it should. Simply stopping this
bartering would work wonders with banks' attitudes and payment system
efficiency.
Take that prop away from the banking system and Australia would have
progressively cheaper and better payment facilities.
This is widely known but 'never' said -- on the contrary the community is
continually misled. A new policy agency would soon 'know it' and soon
promote needed reforms.
The Parliamentary Committee hearing on Friday 31 May could gently expose the
nonsense inherent in current arrangements.
Peter Mair
20 May 2002
Feedback to Peter Mair at
pmair@ezy.net.au
APPENDIX: HOW THE CREDIT CARD STORY DEVELOPED
One useful approach to appreciating the studied ineffectiveness of public
policy approaches to the retail banking industry is of course an analysis of
the transcripts of previous 'hearings' of Reserve Bank views put to the
Parliamentary "Banking" Committee.
Commencing in December 1998, the Committee has had two opportunities each
year to 'hear' the Reserve Bank address payment system policy issues (except
for this current financial year when there will be only this one hearing on
31 May). Credit card schemes are a topical focal point among a range of
possibilities.
Pre-Cruickshank
Prior to the release of the UK 'Cruickshank report' in March 2000, the
Reserve Bank was largely dismissive of concerns about credit card schemes.
In December 1998, responding to a question about a lack of competition in
credit card schemes, the answer was, "No. We do not have any responsibility
for the banking sector per se". The clear impression given to the Committee
was that credit card schemes were not in the Reserve Bank's range, but may
have been the business of some other policy agency.
Mid-1999, just before the 'cash for comment' scandal broke, was the high
point of RBA hubris. The timing was impeccable. In June 1999, the Reserve
Bank played a 'trump card' releasing a major policy statement and supporting
documentation, one day before a scheduled meeting with the Committee that
was overwhelmed. This pre-emptory strike triumphed the tritely true but
largely irrelevant observation that 'bank margins had fallen by more than
bank fees had increased". A qualification was 'accepted', that some -- the
non-borrowing poor -- may have been net losers now a once 'free service' had
its subsidy withdrawn. However, a prospective role for the regulation of
bank fees and charges was dismissed (using the 'margins' evidence) prior to
an acknowledgment that "if there was gouging going on .... the situation
would be different". (The regulatory tide turned the following month when
the banks were revealed to be having a lend of the community -- 'cash for
comment' -- 'cash for comment').
Implicitly, apparently, it was not then known that 'gouging' was going on
but the dawning was getting close. In September 1999 the ACCC launched an
action against the banks for 'price fixing' and was 'joined' in a process of
'studying' credit card schemes with the RBA.
By November 1999 the tide had turned -- not least because the Committee was
then briefed better on payments policy issues, including the mechanics of
the bank credit card rort. The previously lauded triumph of 'margins over
fees' was put in a sensibly broader context and the reduction in margins
correctly attributed to "massive cuts in costs" (largely shifted to
Australia Post and customers denied 'branch' services). More importantly the
RBA noted "a huge increase in transactions using credit cards" and went on
to say "we are sufficiently interested in this subject that we have started
a study of it through the Payments System Board ... ". One can only wonder
what the RBA previously saw when they read the credit card statistics they
had been collecting for some years.
Post Cruickshank
The 'Cruickshank Report' of a UK banking inquiry in March 2000, was
reasonably insightful and forthright in its analysis of banking policy
issues -- especially credit card interchange fees. However, it was also
notable for clearly articulating the consequences of what it called the 'old
contract' between the Bank of England and the UK banks. Under the 'old
contract' the broader public interest was subordinated and banks were given
the feather-bedded luxury of a non-competitive regulatory regime protecting
their profitability, in exchange for doing what they were told and keeping
banking politics relatively cool. Not unlike the situation in Australia, so
to speak.
The upshot was that the Bank of England lost responsibility for banking
industry policy to a reconstituted Office of Fair Trading (the UK's ACCC).
Australia's Reserve Bank could see this writing clearly on the wall and
faced the embarrassment of losing a policy responsibility (for payment
system competition and efficiency) it had only just been given. Its attitude
changed quickly. Ironically, in the event, the UK's OFT is yet to strike a
blow against credit card schemes. As of now, the main impact of the
Cruickshank recommendations has probably been on the Reserve Bank of
Australia. Fairly ironic.
When the Parliamentary "Banking" Committee again 'heard' from the Reserve
Bank in May 2000, the first question on payments policy issues was not
surprisingly about the implications of the Cruickshank report for Australia.
Suddenly, credit card schemes had become "a very interesting subject" to the
RBA and it was "simply trying to find out what is going on and what the
flows of fees are" -- although the community should have contained their
expectations because it was concurrently said to be "intensely complicated".
These encouraging signs were nonetheless qualified later in the hearing when
it was commented that: "We are not a consumer protection agency at the
Reserve Bank".
Left unsaid was that enough detail of the excesses of banks' credit card
schemes had been sufficiently well known for some years to warrant strong
regulatory action that was never taken. The study was touted as 'new'.
Things about credit cards were clearly moving quickly and when the 'hearing'
of the RBA was rejoined in December 2000, it was against the backdrop of the
then recently published report on transaction-card schemes prepared in the
Reserve Bank but published jointly with the ACCC. Among other things, which
agency was responsible for competition policy issues about credit cards was
said to be 'fuzzy'. By then of course the Reserve Bank had more or less
decided to take over the prosecution of credit card policy issues with the
banks, ostensibly because the prosecution launched by ACCC was about to "get
bogged down legally". All this came to pass at Easter 2001 when the RBA
'designated' credit card schemes and the ACCC conceded the transfer of this
responsibility. Remarkably, the RBA never mentioned to the Banking Committee
that is own powers were untested and likely to be challenged, as the banks
had always promised. (As noted, the ACCC is about to re-enter this debate
through its 'investigation' of the banks' BPay scheme modeled on the credit
card arrangement, complete with an interchange fee)
One question at a time
By May 2001 the game was on in earnest. Among other bon mots -- "credit
cards are the biggest issue at the moment" -- was tendered as an explanation
of why needed action was not being taken to follow up previous assessments
that the customers were also being creamed by excessive fees for ATM and
debit card transactions.
The "Banking" Committee was not impressed, very sensibly asking then for "a
total policy approach" and subsequently issuing a press statement headed
"Reserve Bank told to get its act together" -- and requesting that
interchange fees on ATM and EFTPOS transactions be fixed 'as soon as
possible". The Reserve Bank was not accommodating on the day, or
subsequently. That apparent disregard of Parliament is reasonably a matter
of some concern -- especially when the previous history of mishandling this
'total policy' matter reveals so much to be desired. A concern likely to be
reinforced shortly by the probable exposure of the Payments System
legislation as inadequate to the task of promptly delivering what the
Reserve Bank regards as good public policy. Alan Fels would be wryly amused.
The Parliamentary Committee is about to realise that it has been 'yes
ministered' -- a costly, pointless legal stoush will further delay a
properly coordinated and effective approach to regulating the retail
payments system. Time slips away -- and the money keeps rolling in, for the
banks.
One could say that it is appropriate for the Reserve Bank to make decisions
independently about its payments policy responsibilities, as with its
monetary policy decisions. Against that stands a long history of inaction on
issues about competition and efficiency in retail banking. The Parliament
had every right to ask for a 'total policy approach'. And beyond that there
can be a fine line between independence and insolence.
The debate rejoined
It is a long time between drinks in this policy wasteland -- and the public
thirst is apparently never to be satisfied. Dawdling ineffectiveness begs
the question of any resolute intention to bring the retail payments system
to order about its efficiency and competitiveness.
A couple of questions should have been asked and answered some years ago,
* first, should the trade practices law proscribe uniform pricing agreements
that have not been cleared by the competition policy authority?; and
* second, why is a line of credit not offered on debit card accounts?
We live in hope.
Peter Mair