|
Consultation Regulatory Impact Statement August 2008
Responsible lending practices in relation to consumer credit cards
Prepared for the Ministerial Council on Consumer Affairs (now the Consumer Affairs Foundation) - August 2008 Disclaimer Because this publication avoids the use of legal language, information about the law may have been summarised or expressed in general statements. This information should not be relied upon as a substitute for professional legal advice or reference to the actual legislation. Copyright You may copy, distribute, display, download and otherwise freely deal with this information provided you attribute the Office of Fair Trading as the owner. However, you must obtain permission from the Office of Fair Trading if you wish to 1) modify, 2) charge others for access, 3) include in advertising or a product for sale, or 4) obtain profit, from the information.
Important:
For full details, see the Office of Fair Trading’s copyright policy at
http://www.fairtrading.nsw.
© State of New South Wales through the Office of Fair Trading, 2008. Contents SUBMISSIONS........................................................................................................................................................ 3
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY................................................................................................................................... 4
1. OVERVIEW OF THE INDUSTRY........................................................................................................ 14 1.1 INDUSTRY PARTICIPANTS............................................................................................................... 14 1.2 SIZE AND VALUE OF THE INDUSTRY............................................................................................ 14 2. STATEMENT OF THE PROBLEM..................................................................................................... 15 2.1 SIZE AND IMPACT OF THE PROBLEM............................................................................................ 15 2.1.1 Default, write-offs and minimum repayments.................................................................. 16 2.1.2 Debt Collection..................................................................................................................... 16 2.1.3 Bankruptcies.......................................................................................................................... 17 2.1.4 Impact on consumers and potential wider impact......................................................... 17 2.2 WHO IS AFFECTED AND WHY?....................................................................................................... 18 2.3 CURRENT REGULATORY STRUCTURE........................................................................................... 19 2.4 PROBLEMS WITH DISCLOSURE BASED REGULATION................................................................. 23 2.5 GENERATING FUTURE GROWTH IN THE CREDIT CARD MARKET............................................. 23 2.6 REGULATORY FAILURE.................................................................................................................. 26 2.6.1 Application process and timing and nature of information........................................ 26 2.7 SETTING THE CREDIT LIMIT.......................................................................................................... 27 2.7.1 Assessment method............................................................................................................... 31 2.7.2 No incentive for card issuers to change the system....................................................... 31 2.8 MINIMUM REPAYMENT PERCENTAGES....................................................................................... 32 2.8.1 Redress.................................................................................................................................... 33 2.8.2 Enforcement and penalties................................................................................................. 33 2.9 APPROACH TAKEN IN OTHER COUNTRIES TO ADDRESS CREDIT CARD ISSUES..................... 34 3. OBJECTIVES OF GOVERNMENT INTERVENTION................................................................... 35 3.1 GROUPS POTENTIALLY AFFECTED BY GOVERNMENT INTERVENTION.................................. 35 4. POLICY OPTIONS.................................................................................................................................... 36 4.1 OPTION 1: MAINTAIN THE STATUS QUO..................................................................................... 36 4.2 OPTION 2: INCREASED PENALTIES AND BETTER ENFORCEMENT OF THE CURRENT LAW. 37 4.3 OPTION 3: EDUCATION AND INFORMATION.............................................................................. 38 4.4 OPTION 4: SELF REGULATION...................................................................................................... 39 4.5 OPTION 5: CO-REGULATION.......................................................................................................... 40 4.6 OPTION 6: REGULATION................................................................................................................ 41 4.6.1 Option 6.1: change the timing of essential information disclosure........................... 41 4.6.2 Option 6.2: require credit providers to allow consumers to nominate the credit limit sought.................................................................................................................................... 42 4.6.3 Option 6.3: Prohibit the card issuer from providing more credit than the consumer can repay from income without substantial hardship................................................. 42
4.6.4
Option 6.4: Provide relief for consumers by making the debt unenforceable to
the interest charged.................................................................................................................. 44 4.6.5 Option 6.5: Require card issuers to warn consumers about the effect of paying only the minimum repayments................................................................................................... 45 4.6.6 Option 6.6: Require card issuers to increase the minimum repayment percentage for new credit card contracts and for offers of increased credit limits on current cards...................................................................................................................................... 46 4.7 RECOMMENDED OPTION................................................................................................................ 47 5. IMPACT ANALYSIS................................................................................................................................. 47 5.1 OPTION 1: MAINTAIN THE STATUS QUO..................................................................................... 47 5.1.1 Evaluation............................................................................................................................. 49 1 5.2 OPTION 2: INCREASED PENALTIES AND BETTER ENFORCEMENT OF THE CURRENT LAW. 50 5.2.1 Evaluation............................................................................................................................. 51 5.3 OPTION 3: EDUCATION AND INFORMATION.............................................................................. 52 5.3.1 Evaluation............................................................................................................................. 53 5.4 OPTION 4: SELF REGULATION...................................................................................................... 54 5.5 OPTION 5: CO-REGULATION......................................................................................................... 54 5.6 OPTION 6: REGULATION................................................................................................................ 54 5.7 OPTION 6.1: CHANGE THE TIMING OF ESSENTIAL INFORMATION DISCLOSURE.................. 54 5.7.1 Evaluation............................................................................................................................. 55 5.8 OPTION 6.2: REQUIRE CREDIT PROVIDERS TO ALLOW CONSUMERS TO NOMINATE THE CREDIT LIMIT SOUGHT.................................................................................................................................. 55 5.8.1 Evaluation............................................................................................................................. 57 5.9 OPTION 6.3: PROHIBIT THE CARD ISSUER FROM PROVIDING MORE CREDIT THAN THE CONSUMER CAN REPAY FROM INCOME WITHOUT SUBSTANTIAL HARDSHIP........................ 58 5.9.1 Evaluation............................................................................................................................. 61 5.10 OPTION 6.4: PROVIDE RELIEF FOR CONSUMERS BY MAKING THE DEBT UNENFORCEABLE TO THE EXTENT THAT IT EXCEEDS AN AMOUNT GRANTED IN ACCORDANCE WITH OPTION 6.3, INCLUDING INTEREST CHARGED................................................................................................... 62 5.10.1 Evaluation........................................................................................................................... 64 5.11 OPTION 6.5: REQUIRE CARD ISSUERS TO WARN CONSUMERS ABOUT THE EFFECT OF PAYING ONLY THE MINIMUM REPAYMENTS............................................................................................. 64 5.11.1 Evaluation........................................................................................................................... 66 5.12 OPTION 6.6: REQUIRE CARD ISSUERS TO INCREASE THE MINIMUM REPAYMENT PERCENTAGE FOR NEW CREDIT CARD CONTRACTS AND FOR OFFERS OF INCREASED CREDIT LIMITS ON CURRENT CARDS............................................................................................................................... 66 5.12.1 Evaluation........................................................................................................................... 68 6. CONSULTATION...................................................................................................................................... 68 6.1 FUTURE CONSULTATION PROCESS................................................................................................ 71 7. EVALUATION AND REVIEW............................................................................................................... 71
2 Submissions
All interested individuals and organisations are invited to comment on the Ministerial Council on Consumer Affairs’ Responsible Lending Practices in Relation to Consumer Credit Cards Consultation Regulatory Impact Statement.
The Regulatory
Impact Statement is available for downloading at:
Businesses affected by this legislation should identify in their submissions any costs and benefits they might anticipate from the proposals in qualitative and quantitative terms. These should relate to individual options and not be in terms of unsupported general comments.
Comments in writing should be emailed, posted or faxed to:
Senior Project Manager (Credit)
Policy & Strategy
Division PARRAMATTA NSW 2124
Fax: (02) 9338 8918 e-mail: policy@oft.commerce.nsw.gov.au
Closing date for submissions is 3 October 2008. 3 Executive Summary
The problem this consultation regulatory impact statement seeks to address is that asmall percentage, but substantial number of consumers are burdened with ongoingunmanageable credit card debt which appears to be occasioned by a number of factors, including inadequate protection from consumer credit laws. While the percentage of affected consumers is relatively small compared to the much larger percentage of consumers who manage their cards successfully, the impact on the affected consumers is severe, both financially and in its social impact. Major intervention in the consumer credit market has already occurred with the commencement of the Consumer Credit Code (the Code) in all jurisdictions in 1996. The Code provides relevant information to consumers about the costs and conduct of the loan. In the event that consumers are treated unfairly, the Code relies on consumers taking independent action to deal with unfair practices.
The consumers that are the centre of concern in this paperare those who have low financial literacy and do not appreciate the implications of, first, spending to the limitand second, paying only the minimum repayment. Others may have an unrealistic appreciation of their capacity to repay. This group of consumers generally consists of low income, less well educated consumers, and may include the demographic found to have the lowest financial literacy - young people and the elderly.
The problems outlined in this paper suggest that the following are factors that contribute to problematic levels of consumer credit card debt: •Essential information is received at a time when it is unlikely to be useful;
•Credit
providers’ assessment practices
maximise the amount of credit •Minimum repayment percentages are set at a very low level;
•The
legislative requirements are remedial, not preventative, and the remedy Government intervention therefore will aim to: 1. Assist consumer choice of competitively priced credit card products; 2. Adequately protect consumers, especially vulnerable or disadvantaged consumers, from lending practices which irresponsibly provide continuing credit at levels which cannot be repaid without substantial hardship; While at the same time:
3. Minimising the effect on consumers who manage their cards satisfactorily.
Credit card debt issues are relevant to all jurisdictions. The Ministerial Council on Consumer Affairs has acknowledged the importance of this issue by including it on the national agenda.
4 Proposals for standard setting and regulatory initiatives which are made at a national level and which have the potential to restrict competition are required to include evidence that the competitive effects of the regulation have been considered; that the benefits outweigh the likely costs; and that any proposed response is no more restrictive than necessary in the public interest.
This document sets out the problems reported in the marketplace and identifies those structural elements which are considered to be an impediment to effective marketplace solutions. Possible regulatory and non-regulatory approaches are canvassed and options are set out, with analysis of the potential costs and benefits to the community. Comparisons of relative benefits and costs of policy options The objective is always to quantify benefits and costs of proposed options as much as possible. However, when dollars and cent values are not available, a qualitative assessment of potential costs and benefits is useful, as is the relative capacity of the option to meet the objectives of intervention.
Tabular presentation can assist comparison. This will help if, as is likely, a suite of policy instruments is to be considered (eg education and information combined with one or more regulatory options).
The benefits (‘pros’) and costs (‘cons’) of these options are summarised in
the tables Interested parties are asked to contribute to the information contained in these tables by supplying financial impact data for the purposes of obtaining the most accurate set of benefits and costs, and other knowledge, on which to base final decisions.
The options are:
Option 1: Maintain the status quo Option 2: Increased penalties and better enforcement of the current law Option 3: Education and information Option 4: Self-regulation Option 5: Co-regulation Regulatory options:
Option 6.1: Change the timing of essential information disclosure Option 6.2: Require credit card providers to allow consumers to nominate the credit limit sought Option 6.3: Prohibit the card issuer from providing more credit than the consumer can repay from income without substantial hardship Option 6.4: Provide relief for consumers by making the debt unenforceable to the extent it exceeds an amount granted in accordance with option 6.3, including interest charged Option 6.5: Require card issuers to warn consumers about the effect of paying only the minimum repayments Option 6.6: Require card issuers to increase the minimum repayment percentage for new credit card contracts and for offers of increased credit limits on current cards
Option 1 - Maintain the status quo
6
Option 2 - Increased penalties and better enforcement of the current law
7
Option 3 - Education and information
This option is to be considered as part of the status quo. Option 5 - Co - regulation Not considered a viable option.
8 Regulatory Options Option 6.1 - Change the timing of essential information disclosure
Option 6.2 - Require credit providers to allow consumers to nominate the credit limit sought
9
Option 6.3 - Prohibit the card issuer from providing more credit than the consumer can pay from income without substantial hardship
10
Option 6.4 - Provide relief for consumers making the debt unenforceable to
the 6.3, including interest charged.
11
Option 6.5 - Require card issuers to warn consumers about the effect of paying only the minimum repayments
12
Option 6.6 -Require card issuers to increase the minimum repayment percentage for new card contracts and for offers of increased credit limits on current cards
13
1. Overview of the Industry 1.1 Industry participants The “industry” referred to in this consultation RIS is that which deals in continuing credit accessed by a card. A continuing credit contract is defined in the Consumer Credit Code as a credit contract under which - (a) multiple advances of credit are contemplated; and (b) the amount of available credit ordinarily increases as the amount of credit is reduced.
This categorisation includes store cards. The focus of the discussion will be on credit regulated by the Consumer Credit Code, which is uniform in all states and territories, and regulates credit which is predominantly for personal, domestic or household use. Credit cards are issued by individual financial institutions which set the annual fee, interest free period, the interest rate and other conditions associated with the card. The card associations, such as Visa, Mastercard and, formerly, Bankcard, manage the brand. They establish and maintain rules and regulations covering such issues as membership, governance, technical specifications, procedures for the interchange of transactions and the setting of interchange fees (before Reserve Bank intervention), and dispute resolution.1
The banks have,
until recently, dominated the card issuing market. While they are still the
major issuers, there has been an influx in recent times of non bank lenders
such as Virgin Money, Aussie, Wizard (GE) and GE Money entering the market.
GE issues
in its own right and also funds store cards. American Express issues both
credit cards and charge cards. Charge cards are not considered credit for
the Store cards are issued in the name of the store, but the funds are usually supplied by large financiers such as GE. As at 4 April 2008 Cannex listed 77 card issuers on its website, the largest of these having 23 cards on offer. Market share statistics for all the issuers are not available.
1.2 Size and value of the industry It should be noted that data sources may not always separate UCCC credit from credit which is for business use. Where this is the case, that fact will be noted in the text and some guidance given as to the proportion considered to be consumer credit. It is also noted that available data will not give a complete picture.
Total card spending in the year ended December 2007 on personal credit cards
was
$169,477 million. Balances outstanding for the year ending December 2007
for
cards issued by banks for personal use were reported to be $39,005 million.
This figure includes that percentage of cardholder debt which is attributed to
transactional use, that is, will be paid fully on receipt of the account.
However, the annual “revolve” rate stood at 72.1%.2 These figures do not
include card issuers other than Australian Prudential Regulatory Authority
(APRA) regulated institutions, neither do they include store cards unless
issued by a bank.
1 Debit and Credit Card Schemes in Australia, October 2000, Reserve Bank of Australia & Australian Competition and Consumer Commission, p.18.
During the last three years, when the number of accounts has grown by 22.1% and the value of purchases by 32.8%, the growth of total credit limits has increased by 44.7% with balances rising by 49.1%.3 It is evident from this data that balances outstanding on credit cards have grown at a faster rate than the other indices. The annual repayment rate, at 100%4, suggests that consumers are paying what they spend but that balances are not being paid down but are increasing.
The value of card products to the card issuers is less accessible. While
credit cards 2. Statement of the problem
The problem, as seen by Government agencies and consumer advocates, is that a small percentage, but substantial number of consumers are burdened with ongoing unmanageable credit card debt which appears to be occasioned by a number of factors, including inadequate protection from consumer credit laws. While the percentage of affected consumers is relatively small compared to the much larger percentage of consumers who manage their cards successfully, the impact on the affected consumers is severe, both financially and in its social impact. It can be asked why consumers should not take total responsibility for their choices. This paper suggests that there may be a number of contributing factors. These are discussed below.
2.1 Size and Impact of the problem
This section
attempts to identify, from available data, the impact of unmanageable
2 MWE Consulting, Australian Credit Cards Report, December 2007, based on APRA data. Cardholders who do not pay off their balance in full each month are said to “revolve”, that is carry over their balance and therefore pay interest on the account. The “revolve” rate for each month is averaged over the year in the percentage quoted.
3 MWE Consulting, December 2007. 4 MWE Consulting, Australian Credit Cards Report, November 2007. 5 MWE Consulting, December 2007.
15
card issuer nor
the central bank or prudential regulator publishes these statistics on a The inclusion of debt collection figures adds weight to the assertion in this paper that the problem of credit card indebtedness affects a significant number of people. 2.1.1 Default, write-offs and minimum repayments
The figures below
are from different sources and different timeframes and can not
In September 2004,
credit cards 90 days overdue (technically in default) were said to
In research conducted in 2001, card issuers interviewed by the Office of
Fair Trading
Figures supplied
by the Consumer Credit Legal Centre Inc (NSW) to the Senate 2.1.2 Debt Collection
As refinancing may
disguise possible problems with credit card repayment, so the
6 Reserve Bank of Australia, “Box A: Credit Card indicators”, Financial Stability Review, September 2004.
16
2.1.3 Bankruptcies
Excessive use of
credit was the underlying cause of insolvency in 27.2% (5555 A partner at chartered accountant Hall Chadwick, Mr Paul Leroy, was quoted in March 2007 as saying that the inability to meet credit card payments is the biggest reason people go bankrupt.8 2.1.4 Impact on consumers and potential wider impact The issue of concern in this paper is that a relatively small sector of the community is vulnerable to exploitation by card issuers and, because of a small income base, once in a situation where all income is totally committed to maintenance and servicing debt, there is no way that the consumer can reverse the circumstances in which they have unwittingly become involved. This group of affected consumers will be referred to in this paper as “disadvantaged.”
The personal and
social impact of debt can be severe: it can lead to family As well, the ongoing commitment to interest payments on credit card debt has a major impact on a person’s long term capacity to provide for themselves in respect of housing, health, education and retirement. It is clear that this commitment will exclude expenditure on other goods and services, some of which may be for essential items or health care. There may therefore be increased demands on all helping agencies whether government or community based, to assist those who are unable to provide for themselves, and has implications for pensions, health provision, housing and other government services.
7 Inspector-General in Bankruptcy, Annual report 2005 - 2006, Table 5. 8 Herald Sun, 12 March 2007, p.59.
17 2.2 Who is affected and why? There is a small, but increasing body of research into consumer financial literacy, as well as research into what influences consumer decision-making. In relation to consumer financial literacy, qualitative research conducted by the A C Neilson and the ANZ bank identifies combinations of three main factors which contributed to consumers with borrowings feeling out of control with their finances. The survey was not restricted to credit cards but covered all credit.
The two
predominant factors identified were “unhealthy ways of thinking about
In addition, the
study noted that there was an extensive range of influences acting on
Anecdotal evidence
suggests there is a group of cardholders who simply are not
The consumers that are the centre of concern in this paper are those who
have low
The NSW Consumer Credit Legal Centre took on 15 cases out of a total of 1475 callers to their credit helpline during one year who identified credit card debt as a problem. The cases were chosen on their level of disadvantage to the cardholder, since it was not within the service’s capacity to take on all cases which had merit. Of those 15, the following details are relevant:
18 • 12 were on social security (including largely Disability Support Pension but also Aged Pension, Veteran’s Pension and Parenting Payment); • 1 received Combined Social Security and casual employment; • 1 was employed low income; • 1 was employed medium income; • Many clients had social and health problems including mental illness; • The amount of credit card debt ranged from $5,400 to $70,000; • 13 clients had only one lender, 12 with one card and one with two cards; • One client had two lenders with two cards each; • One client with 5 cards had two lenders and four of the cards were with the same lender. Results of action taken: • Every matter was settled except one where the client went bankrupt becauseof stress before the dispute could progress; • 4 debts were waived completely, usually where there were compassionate grounds in addition to maladministration; • 2 matters were settled on the basis that there would be no reduction in the principal amount outstanding but there would be no further interest or fees and charges accruing;
•
The remainder were settled on a reduction in the principal, usually by 50%
or
The relatively recent discipline of “behavioural economics” has investigated
the ways
Behavioural economics can clearly explain why consumers appear to make
choices
The Wesley Mission
report says that the research suggests there are three factors
• Their exposure to credit options • Their lack of financial literacy and ability to budget
•
Their lack of knowledge about how they can address financial stress before
it
2.3 Current regulatory structure Consumer lending is regulated by the Consumer Credit Code (the Code), which is legislation that is uniform in all states and territories.
The Code regulates the conduct of the credit contract from the first
negotiation up to
19
the contract and the information that must be included in the credit contract. With respect to credit cards, the information provision and the formation of the contract differ from other credit contracts.
Transparency of process is reflected in all aspects of the legislation: any cost, requirement or term of the contract must be made known to the consumer in the contract. This extends to whether a mortgage is taken, and includes the provision of information about the contract to any prospective guarantor.
Statements of
account must be given periodically, the maximum period for a credit
The most important provision in the Code in respect of the responsible
lending issue
Another relevant provision in the Code is: the capacity for the consumer to
negotiate There is a capacity for jurisdictions to diverge from the Uniformity Agreement covering the Code in identified areas, specifically in respect of whether a maximum annual percentage rate is applied, and whether civil penalties are paid into a trust fund for a designated purpose. In addition to these variations, the Australian Capital Territory, under its Fair Trading Act 1992, requires a card issuer to take into consideration when making its initial assessment, or when considering an increased limit, all relevant income and expenditure and financial commitments of the consumer when determining capacity to repay. This legislation was introduced in response to perceived consumer detriment from irresponsible lending practices in that jurisdiction.
At Commonwealth
level, the
Australian Securities and Investments Act 2001
has a
20 transactions involving the granting of more credit than can be repaid by the cardholder, and which fit under the BFSO’s category of “maladministration” are not likely to be covered by the doctrine of unconscionability.9 The only relevant law which applies Australia-wide is therefore the Consumer Credit Code, and that legislation provides only individual redress. Self Regulation
Banks may be subject to self regulation of their services under the Code of Banking Practice (Banking Code). Adherence to the Banking Code is voluntary, however banks that adopt it are contractually bound by their obligations under that document. There is nothing in the Banking Code that is in conflict with the Consumer Credit Code and in general it does not cover the same ground. The Banking Code gives way to the Consumer Credit Code where there is overlap. In relation to the cost of credit, Section 12 of the Banking Code says: “we will make available to you, a potential customer or an appropriate external agency the interest rates and standard fees and charges applicable to a banking service that is a credit service offered by us for use in the preparation of a comparison rate.” There is, however, no formula for calculating a comparison rate for credit cards in contrast to fixed term loans. The range of fees which apply to credit cards are not easily accessible, as discussed in 2.4 below.
In relation to the provision of credit, section 25.1 of the Banking Code
says: “Before
The Banking Code otherwise does not impact on the matters discussed in this paper. The Banking and Financial Services Ombudsman (BFSO) was set up originally as an external dispute resolution scheme for banks that agreed to be bound by its determinations. It now covers other providers of financial services and card issuers including GE Money. Granting credit in excess of what a consumer can repay is categorised as “maladministration” by the Banking and Financial Services Ombudsman. Maladministration in relation to credit cards was identified by the BFSO in its submission to the Senate Inquiry into the wider impacts of household debt as the fastest growing category of all consumer credit complaints. From 2000 to 2004 the number of complaints received in this category grew from 36 to 175, while for personal loans it increased from 19 to 36. For home loans and investment property loans the number of complaints in this category decreased.
The BFSO takes legislative requirements into account when making
determinations
9 BFSO Bulletin 45 March 2005. 10 The BFSO Terms of Reference do not define this term but that document states under
5.1(a) “The Ombudsman may consider disputes about maladministration in
lending or security
21
The Commonwealth Government Consumer and Financial Literacy Taskforce was set up in February 2004 to develop a national strategy for consumer and financial literacy. The Taskforce noted that “while not actually breaching any laws, it is an unfortunate fact that many business operators in Australia continue to act in unethical or unhelpful ways to consumers. A good example of this is the way in which some credit services are marketed towards vulnerable consumers.”13 Initiatives undertaken by the Taskforce include a pilot in the ACT to integrate financial literacy into vocational training. Financial literacy is also being introduced into the school curriculum for years 3, 5, 7 and 9. A website and handbook providing information about money matters was launched, the existence of which was advertised in print, radio and TV.
These initiatives focus on a fundamental understanding of money management
and
always been that, in determining whether there has been maladministration in the lender’s decision, the issue of the applicant’s ability to repay is critical.” (p.5) 11 ANZ Corporate Responsibility Report 2005, p36. 12 Ibid. 13 Ibid, p.xiii
22 2.4 Problems with disclosure based regulation Major intervention in the consumer credit market has already occurred with the commencement of the Consumer Credit Code (the Code) in all jurisdictions in 1996. The Code is based on “truth in lending” provisions which assume that, given full, or at least, adequate knowledge of the nature of the credit product and the terms of the transaction with the supplier, consumers will make choices in their own best interests. A further assumption is that the information will be relevant, timely and freely available, and also that the consumer will have the capacity to fully appreciate the meaning and relevance of the information.
The Code, therefore, provides relevant information to consumers about the costs and conduct of the loan. In the event that consumers are treated unfairly, the Code relies on consumers taking independent action to deal with unfair practices.
The theoretical basis for disclosure-based legislation is currently under
question, as Reliance on disclosure to provide consumer protection can be seen to result in the risks associated with making choices of complex products being borne by the consumer alone. Many consumers are simply not up to the task.
Disclosure-based
regulation, while transferring risk to consumers, is assumed to This, along with the relatively large number of card applicants who are relatively unskilled in financial management, undermines the capacity of consumers to exercise their demand-side power.
2.5 Generating future growth in the credit card market The late 1990s saw credit cards vigorously marketed, and the growth of that market is now facing saturation. This leaves the card industry with the challenge of finding ways to generate new growth. Options may include: seeking new markets; finding new ways of encouraging spending via a credit card; and increasing income from existing spending patterns.
With regard to
seeking new markets, the youth market has recently been targeted period (1% of net purchases). The interest rate is high at 16.99%. Young people have the lowest financial literacy rates and no credit history. Those
23 that come to the notice of consumer agencies may have income only from part time or temporary employment. Other lenders are targeting high risk consumers other than the young, but with very high interest rate products. With respect to encouraging spending, credit card data shows that, historically, the growth in the level of balances owing has kept pace with the level of credit limits. The recent aggressive marketing of increased credit limits may therefore be an attempt to encourage greater use of the card. The fact that balances are growing at a faster rate than credit limits could suggest that consumers are now paying less of the outstanding balance than before, perhaps as a consequence of limits increasing beyond a cardholder’s repayment capacity. Another strategy that may encourage spending is a system of tiered interest rates that has been introduced by some card issuers. This “rewards” consumers with higher spends by reducing the interest rate as the amount spent increases.
With regard to increased income from existing cards, reduced minimum
repayment
All of these strategies may be a rational industry response to the reduction
in growth A study undertaken by A C Neilson and the ANZ bank made reference to the lender’s role in “out of control” debt, saying:
“For the majority of people in this qualitative study.………lenders could be
seen as The study concluded that the challenge here is for lenders to market their products responsibly, and to be responsive and appropriately flexible in dealing with consumers in financial hardship.
The Senate
Inquiry into household debt considered credit card debt in their
14
ACNielson, ANZ “Understanding Personal Debt and Financial Difficulty in
Australia”, Nov
24
“However, the Committee is persuaded that some of the lending practices within the credit and charge card industry that have been described during the inquiry are substandard and are not in accordance with the standards of practice which the banking industry itself regards as acceptable.
In particular, the Committee is concerned that the practice of offering
consumers
The Committee went
on to recommend that uniform consumer credit legislation
The Committee further recommended that the Code be amended to mandate the provision, in a clear and easily understood manner, of a summary of the interest rates, key fees and core terms and conditions of card interest rates in all credit card promotional literature. This requirement was also recommended to apply to charge cards and interest free periods offered by retailers.
In a study carried out by the Saint Paul Foundation in the US, the committee comprising card issuers, financial counsellors, bank regulators, educators and elected officials commented that:
“Within the industry, there is limited incentive to help steer people away from financial trouble until it is too late. The most profitable customers for a card issuer are those long term cardholders who carry a balance, pay late, and occasionally surpass their credit limit, thus incurring additional fees”.16 This comment would apply equally to the credit card market in Australia.
The St. Paul Foundation study addresses the efficiency of the market and
concludes
“The market’s discipline and sophistication generally result in efficient operation (of the industry), but this is not always the case. The consequences of irresponsible behaviour by the industry are not always immediate and can, in fact, lag for many years; such issuers may not be “caught” by the financial marketplace until much damage has been done to both investors and cardholders.”17
The study goes on to comment that while issuers determine the level of
charge-offs
15 The Senate Economics References Committee, “Consenting adults deficits and household debt”, October 2005, p104. 16 The Saint Paul foundation, Phase 2 of the Committee exploring responsible selling and use of credit cards within vulnerable populations, Feb. 2003, p.21. 17 Ibid, p. 20 18 Ibid, p21.
25
This study
suggests that the problem of credit card debt should not be seen in
2.6 Regulatory failure The experience of a significant number of cardholders has served to identify failures in the legislative approach taken by the Code. These are set out below. 2.6.1 Application process and timing and nature of information In reality, the provision of information at the right time and the capacity of the consumer to use that information fall well short of the ideal. The application process for credit cards is not the same as for other products: there is usually no capacity for consumers to specify the credit limit required, and there is no comprehensive disclosure of interest rates and fees in a precontractual disclosure document, either separate to or as part of a contract document provided for an applicant to sign. Those details are supplied in the letter of offer sent by the issuer when the application has been approved and the credit limit set by the institution, and the card is ready for collection. For this product the Consumer Credit Code allows the contract to be made by using the card.
While the Code
policy is essentially to ensure that consumers are armed with
A credit reference
database stores information that is of use to credit providers for In terms of market failure, search costs for appropriate and useful information are high. The consumer must actively seek out price and feature information from the card issuer before applying for a credit card as opposed to other forms of credit where these are presented in a precontractual disclosure document.
26
2.4 Problems with disclosure based regulation Major intervention in the consumer credit market has already occurred with the commencement of the Consumer Credit Code (the Code) in all jurisdictions in 1996. The Code is based on “truth in lending” provisions which assume that, given full, or at least, adequate knowledge of the nature of the credit product and the terms of the transaction with the supplier, consumers will make choices in their own best interests. A further assumption is that the information will be relevant, timely and freely available, and also that the consumer will have the capacity to fully appreciate the meaning and relevance of the information.
The Code, therefore, provides relevant information to consumers about the costs and conduct of the loan. In the event that consumers are treated unfairly, the Code relies on consumers taking independent action to deal with unfair practices.
The theoretical basis for disclosure-based legislation is currently under
question, as Reliance on disclosure to provide consumer protection can be seen to result in the risks associated with making choices of complex products being borne by the consumer alone. Many consumers are simply not up to the task.
Disclosure-based
regulation, while transferring risk to consumers, is assumed to This, along with the relatively large number of card applicants who are relatively unskilled in financial management, undermines the capacity of consumers to exercise their demand-side power.
2.7 Setting the credit limit
The legislative provisions that were intended to prevent,
or at least deter,
19 Malbon J, “Taking Credit” , September 1999
27 issuers appear to be avoiding the intention of the Code in section 70 (2) (l), the objective of which is to prevent consumers being given more credit they can afford to repay without substantial hardship. This provision gives a court or tribunal the power to reopen the transaction that gave rise to the contract, mortgage or guarantee, if satisfied on the application of the debtor, that the circumstances relating to the relevant credit contract were unjust. The relevant subsection is one of the matters that may be considered by the court. It states:
“whether at the time the contract, mortgage or guarantee was entered into or
changed,
This was included
in the Code to address perceived deficiencies in the Code’s Assessment practices
With respect to
assessment of applicants and the amount of credit granted, card
The major problem
from a consumer perspective is that card issuers are setting Assessment based on minimum repayment
The wording of section 70(2)(l) also provides further
possibilities of wide
20 Monetary Policy and Financial Stability”, I J Macfarlane, Speech to CEDA Annual Dinner, Melbourne, 26 November 2004.
28 minimum repayments it may be that card issuers’ practice of assessing capacity to repay on the basis that they can make the minimum repayment may be interpreted by credit card issuers as within the letter of the law if not the spirit. Information supplied to the Office of Fair Trading in 2001 by card issuers confirmed that applicants were generally assessed on their capacity to repay minimum repayments (or thereabouts) and the credit limits set accordingly. Their living expenses were, in many cases, assessed on a figure comparable to the “Henderson Poverty Line”. Such assessment processes, that factor in minimum repayment amounts and very low living expenses, would allow the credit limit set by the card issuer to be maximised. Since that time the major card issuers have reduced their minimum repayment percentages, which would allow higher credit limits to be set, and it is unknown whether assessment practices have changed, though the escalation of credit card debt would suggest otherwise. Credit limit increases
Credit cards are
probably the only product in relation to which an offer of an
Card issuers may
also offer increased limits when a consumer is spent to the limit
Consumer response to a limit that is set too high The consumer will not know until they receive the letter of acceptance from the credit provider what their credit limit may be, since they have not been able to specify what is needed on the application form. Once a limit is granted which might be in excess of that a consumer might choose, behavioural economics research/analysis suggests that where action by a consumer is needed to reduce that limit, only a very small percentage of consumers would do so.21 This results in outcomes such as demonstrated in the following case study:
One young man had told the bank official he wanted a $500 limit. Since there
was no field
21 Louise Sylvan, 2006 Consumer Affairs Victoria Lecture in Honour of Dr Maureen Brunt AO.
29
$10,000 limit. He also had a car loan with the bank and was earning $420 a week. He could not repay the debt.22 Asset lending The lack of specificity in 70(2)(l) may also result in card issuers relying on the fact that a consumer has an asset to ensure capacity to repay, but without necessarily taking security over that asset. While there is no specific reference in the Code to asset lending, this section was intended to prevent such occurrences. In practice it appears not to be given this interpretation. The Credit Card Report undertaken for Visa in 2002 states: “On face value, this suggests that very low-income earners obtain a much higher limit relative to income than high-income earners. In part this will simply reflect the fact that consumption accounts for a higher share of income in low-income groups. Additionally and importantly, income is only one of the indicators of capacity to repay credit card debt used by financial institutions to decide credit card limits. Financial institutions also take into account assets and liabilities.”23 To set credit limits on the unacknowledged basis that a consumer can sell what may be their only asset in order to repay is not consistent with the truth-in-lending basis for the Code, which relies on the consumer being aware of the intentions of the credit provider and any possible obligations on their side.
Transparency of
intention in relation to mortgages is fundamental to the Code
The unjust contract provisions, in addition to section 70(2)(l), contain two
matters for
This confirms that even if a mortgage is taken there is a need to make the
consumer
22 Supriya Singh et al, op cit. 23 VISA, “The Credit Card Report”, November 2002, pp 19-20. 24 Mark Bengtsson in “The New Consumer Credit Code”, Butterworths, 1994, p78.
30 the credit on the basis that the consumer would have to sell an asset to repay, but this is not known to the consumer, this could certainly be considered unjust. The NSW Consumer Credit Legal Centre has negotiated a number of settlements in respect of asset-based lending on credit cards, where the credit provider has been challenged on the basis that this was unjust. Since none of these proceed to court, there is no body of law to effect systemic change.
There have been
determinations by the Court in respect of mortgages over a The research paper from which the two cases above were sourced also quotes the NSW Law Reform Commission as saying: “Asset-based lending, where the borrower and guarantor appear unable on the face of the transaction to be able to repay the loan, is a feature of improvident transactions,” while the Banking and Financial Services Ombudsman states: “No banker should rely on the realisation of assets held as security as the primary source of repayment and the banker must be satisfied that there is a clear repayment source.”27 The practice of assessing a consumer’s capacity to repay on the basis that they can sell an asset is not, therefore, consistent with the policy basis of the Code, nor is it sanctioned by the courts in cases where this issue has been raised. 2.7.1 Assessment method
Credit providers
readily agree that they use credit scoring methods rather than 2.7.2 No incentive for card issuers to change the system
There is no
incentive for credit providers to comply with the spirit of the legislation
25 Elkofairi v Permanent Trustee Co (2003) 11 BPR 20,841 26 Small & Ors v Gray & Ors (2004) NSWSC 97 (5 March 2004)
27
Nicola Howell for Consumer Credit Legal Service Inc (Vic), “Solicitor
lending to consumers:
31
2.8 Minimum repayment percentages
When the consumer has received the information and picked up their card,
they will
Cannex, a
financial services research group, recently called for card issuers to
Minimum repayment
percentages are, in the case of the major card issuers, 2% or This is equally true of the offers to increase credit limits. While the major bank card issuers will provide information on how this increases the minimum repayment amount, the flow-on effect of this on long term commitments is not known to the consumer, nor is it accessible to those unable to make the calculations themselves. While responsible use of credit is closely related to social and cultural factors, this paper is concerned with the inadequacy of Code requirements in relation to responsible lending and the effect this is having on those consumers who are not sufficiently financially literate to understand the implications of relatively high credit limits and low minimum repayment requirements.
This is not an
issue for the consumer who chooses not to pay more because they opt
32 The Code does not require any information to be given which will alert the consumer to the effect of drawing down their limit and making the minimum repayment required. Nor does it regulate the level at which a minimum repayment can be set. 2.8.1 Redress The Code’s approach to redress is to provide that a consumer (or guarantor or mortgagor) can apply for the contract to be reopened as unjust, on the basis that, at the time the contract was entered into or changed, the credit provider knew, or could have ascertained by reasonable enquiry, that the contract could not be repaid according to its terms without substantial hardship.
It should be
noted that this provision is not a “stand alone”
prohibition of
In a study
connecting credit and low income in the United States, “The poor pay
While this
provides relief for a small number of consumers, the percentage of The safety net of appropriate redress mechanisms intended to protect the interests of those consumers who fall foul of the process can be seen as flawed in that those who are most in need of assistance are the least likely to be able to negotiate the largely self-help process. 2.8.2 Enforcement and penalties There is nothing in the Code which puts a positive obligation on industry to assess a consumer’s capacity to repay according to specified guidelines
Re-opening
provisions such as section 70 do not prohibit credit providers from
28 Quoted in “Families at Risk Deciding on Personal Debt”, Supriya Singh et al, May 2005.
33
be made an offence
under the law if the contract is found by the court to be unjust.
2.9 Approach taken in other countries to address credit card
In the United
States, the regulatory focus has been on the minimum repayment
This approach
would mean that consumers would accrue less interest and, therefore,
The recently
enacted US Bankruptcy Abuse Prevention Act of 2005 will require credit
The “number” referred to in the Minimum Payment Warning above is toll free,
and is
29 CreditShack.org/archive/53-minimum-payment-rising.html 30 Bankruptcy Abuse Prevention and Consumer Protection Act of 2005, section 1301. 34
The “health warning” such as outlined above, when tested on consumers informally in the context of a youth debt survey in New South Wales, elicited a major reaction in that those consumers had no concept of how long they would be carrying their credit card debt. While they indicated a commitment to clearing their card debts this was not a formal study that tracked those consumers over time.
In 2004, the Bank of Thailand announced new measures to regulate the credit
card
In the UK, in
amendments to the Consumer Credit Act 1974 passed in 2006, the 3. Objectives of government intervention The problems outlined above in Section 2 suggest that the following are factors that contribute to consumer overindebtedness:
• Essential information is received at a time when it is unlikely to be useful;
•
Credit providers’ assessment practices maximise the amount of credit
• Minimum repayment percentages are set at a very low level;
•
The legislative requirements are remedial, not preventative, and the remedy
Government intervention therefore will aim to:
1. Assist consumer choice of competitively priced credit card products; 2. Adequately protect consumers, especially vulnerable or disadvantaged consumers, from lending practices which irresponsibly provide continuing credit at levels which cannot be repaid without substantial hardship;
While at the same time: 3. Minimising the effect on consumers who manage their cards satisfactorily.
3.1 Groups potentially affected by Government intervention
There are four main groups that could be affected by any Government
intervention:
35
partially funded
by government. Consumers can further be divided into “mainstream”,
4. Policy options
The relative merits of a range of options are set out below. This section
will examine
4.1 Option 1: Maintain the status quo This is an option under which no changes would be made to the current regulatory structure. The external environment may, nevertheless, impose changes. Additional card issuers might conceivably enter the market. While increased competition may meet objective 1 for mainstream consumers, it would not therefore do so for disadvantaged consumers. As well, increased competition may encourage further reductions in minimum repayment requirements. With this scenario it is likely that growth in outstanding balances would continue to outstrip growth in account numbers and purchases. Card issuers would continue to benefit from the long term interest commitment of a significant number of cardholders. While one card issuer has made a commitment to not offering increased limits in circumstances where consumers only make the minimum repayment, this does not address the excessive amount of credit granted initially. In the absence of any change to the status quo, only a small percentage of overcommitted consumers would be assisted to obtain relief from debt. Consumers have reported to consumer advocates that card issuers currently are unwilling to negotiate on their debt. It appears, therefore that, unless represented by government or community advocates the majority of affected consumers would be unable to obtain relief even if they were aware that this was a possibility.
There is nothing to suggest that the status quo would provide any impetus for systemic change from either consumer demand or environmental factors. Current trends suggest that very little could be expected to change in either the major card issuer initial assessment practices or in the choice and use of a credit card facility by the more disadvantaged consumers. Disadvantaged consumers would continue to incur long term interest commitments and suffer the financial stresses associated with unmanageable debt.
Retail business
may also be affected by significant numbers of consumers having
36 among the earliest affected by negative consumer sentiment resulting in consumers paying down debt rather than spending. There would be little difference between this phenomenon and that of consumers having no discretionary spending power. This option would, therefore, not meet Objective 2 and would meet Objective 3.
4.2 Option 2: Increased penalties and better enforcement of
“Enforcement”, in
this context, could not involve prosecution since there is no offence The most that could be done under the current regulatory scheme is for government and other agencies to increase the number of negotiations undertaken on behalf of debtors who register complaints. Such negotiations are already undertaken by governments and community organisations. It is noted above, however, that many consumers are not aware of the potential for relief if contact is not made with either government or community organisations.
The Australian
Financial Review has commented that a relatively new service in
Such debt
reduction services are commercial enterprises, and reports from
Some outreach strategies in the form of advertising and information dissemination would probably need to be employed to increase consumer awareness of their rights and the services available. The success of this would depend on how many consumers could be encouraged to seek assistance, and on the resources available to helping agencies to take up their cases. As also discussed in 2.8.2, no penalties can be applied to provisions such as reopening provisions, but credit providers would, in effect, be penalised to a degree by loss of interest on increased numbers of negotiated accounts. For criminal or civil penalties to be imposed, legislative changes to the Code would be necessary to provide an appropriate measure against which conduct could be judged. This option does not meet Objective 1, may partially meet Objective 2 and meets Objective 3.
37
4.3 Option 3: Education and information
As noted above, current research confirms that consumers make decisions,
financial Research into the effectiveness of education and information strategies suggests that consumers are most likely to be engaged by information if it is targeted or made available when the consumer is most likely to be receptive. In respect of credit cards, consumers are most likely to be receptive to product information in the period between deciding to apply for a credit card and making an application. The Ministerial Council on Consumer Affairs has funded research which will identify what information is most relevant to consumers in relation to a range of credit products, including credit cards, and the optimal timing of that information.
Information about
the conduct of the contract is unlikely to be useful during this
Research shows
that different groups within the community respond best to
Research pilots in the UK tested and developed the capability of Citizens
Advice and
•
To a small group of people (10 or less) with shared needs and interests, practical examples which had day to day and local relevance;
•
As part of a partner agency’s existing programme held in
familiar
•
By bureau workers able to blend sound financial and local knowledge with
31 Daniel Kahneman, Maps of Bounded Rationality: a Perspective on Intuitive Judgement and Choice, December 2002.
38 The evaluation identified significant outcomes for those clients who displayed greater confidence around personal finance resulting in reduced financial exclusion. Importantly, individuals surveyed some months afterwards had:
•
Adhered to budgeting plans and continued to take effective measures to
•
Felt empowered to avoid poor deals, exploitative lending practices
and
This program
demonstrates that well designed programs can make a difference to “at When further information is to hand on strategies with a proven success rate, the Ministerial Council may consider whether expansion of current education and information would be cost effective.
Education and
information about consumers’ rights to redress and the services
It is not possible to predict whether this option would meet Objectives 1
and 2 in the
4.4 Option 4: Self Regulation Banks are the major card issuers and they are subject to the Code of Banking Practice (Banking Code). The “responsible lending” provision of the Banking Code in clause 25.1 currently states: “Before we offer or give you a credit facility (or increase and existing credit facility) we will exercise the care and skill of a diligent and prudent banker in selecting and applying our credit assessment methods and in forming our opinion about your ability to repay it.” This provision was inserted following an independent review of the Banking Code in 2001.
The reviewer of
the Banking Code had proposed a stronger commitment to
32
ECOTEC, “Evaluation of the Citizens Advice National Financial Capability
Project”, June 33 Richard Viney, Review of the Code of Banking Practice Issues Paper, February 2001, p 69.
39 on the consumer’s credit needs and does not require them to make any changes to the way their assessments are conducted.
The impetus for industry self regulation requires a recognition of the need
for change
Subsequently, the
Australian Bankers’ Association put forward draft principles for None of these initiatives addresses the major concern - the amount of credit granted initially and the capacity of the consumer to repay the amount of credit granted. Since card issuers have consistently denied the need for concern about their assessment practices, it is likely that these initiatives have been implemented to assuage community criticisms.
Since there has
been resistance to changing the Banking Code or implement This option would not meet Objectives 1 and 2 but would meet Objective 3.
4.5 Option 5: Co-regulation Co-regulation, as defined by the Office of Best Practice Regulation, “typically refers to the situation where industry develops and administers its own arrangements, but government provides legislative backing to allow the arrangements to be enforced….Sometimes legislation sets out mandatory government standards, but provides that compliance with an industry code can be deemed to comply with those standards. Legislation may also provide for government imposed arrangements in the event that industry does not meet its own arrangements.”
The viability of this option would appear to rest on the industry agreeing to the need for arrangements to deal with a specified problem, and agreement with government as to how to address it.
To date, this has
not occurred. As stated above, there has been resistance to
40 said this, a review of the Banking Code is currently being conducted, and it will be instructive if the provisions are changed, and to what degree.
The Banking Code is currently enforceable in that, once a bank agrees to be bound by the Code, its requirements are a contractual obligation on the bank. These would generally be “enforced” by the Banking and Financial Services Ombudsman if a complaint is made that is not resolved at bank level. There is no suggestion that enforcement of the Code requirements is not working.
The problem, therefore, with this option, is that the precondition of industry agreement as to the existence of a problem and the way in which it could reasonably be addressed, does not exist.
To all intents and purposes there is no difference in this respect from
Self-regulation
4.6 Option 6: Regulation
Regulation of
consumer credit in its current form appears to have failed to prevent Set out below are a set of options which are considered to be appropriate responses to the issues identified above. They may be considered singly or collectively, excepting Options 6.3 and 6.4 which are necessarily connected. They may also be considered in tandem with non-regulatory options outlined above.
4.6.1 Option 6.1: change the timing of essential information
The essential
aspect of the problem identified in 2.6.1, information about the
The timing of information and the form in which it is presented are the
subject of an
41 easily understood manner, of a summary of the interest rates, key features and core terms and conditions of credit card interest rates in all credit card promotional literature. This requirement is also to apply to charge cards and interest free periods offered by consumers.” This Option would meet Objectives 1 and 3, but is unlikely to meet Objective 2 for the majority of disadvantaged consumers because of the characteristics of those consumers outlined above, and in particular in section 2.2.
4.6.2 Option 6.2: require credit providers to allow consumers to There is no provision on the application form for the applicant to nominate the amount of credit limit sought. Option 2 would require card issuers to provide a field on their applications which asks consumers to nominate the maximum limit sought. This would be consistent with other credit products where the consumer is asked to state the amount of credit sought and there appears to be no good reason why it should not also apply to credit cards. The legislation would prohibit the card issuer from granting credit in excess of that requested by the consumer.
This option would meet objectives 2 and 3.
4.6.3 Option 6.3: Prohibit the card issuer from providing more substantial hardship. While the policy intention of the current provisions in the Consumer Credit Code is to ensure consumers are not given more credit than they can afford to repay, in practice this has not been successful. This results in part from the framing of S70(2)(l) along with the fact that it is a reopening provision rather than a preventive mechanism. Reliance on consumers taking action through the court or tribunal discriminates against those least able to defend their interests and allows credit providers to continue their current assessment practices. This option as a prohibition, puts the onus on the card issuer to ensure that consumers are not, at the time they enter into a contract, provided with more credit than they could repay from income without substantial hardship.
The majority of
card issuers already require information on income, other financial
“Substantial hardship” would be defined to ensure that
there is a realistic
42 roughly equivalent to personal loans so that it is reasonable that they should be able to be repaid over a similar period if the consumer so desires. The longest period over which a personal loan is repaid is seven years, and this would appear appropriate as a guide for a timeframe for determining capacity to repay the amount of credit granted if fully drawn.
The Senate
Economics Committee inquiry recommendation 7 suggested (a) asks the debtor for a statement of the debtor’s financial situation, including -
(i) income; and (ii) all credit accounts and applicable limits and balances; and (iii) repayment commitments: and (b) takes the statement into account in making the assessment.
While this ACT
initiative requires the consumer’s income and expenditure to be taken
An alternative
approach was recently by the Bank of Thailand in 2004, which requires
The current provisions in section 70(2)(l) of the Code are qualified by the
inclusion of
The concept of
repaying from income has been added to the proposals outlined in
43
the sale of an asset, usually the family home. Asset lending is again being reported and, when retirees are increasingly being offered credit cards or increased limits without any assessment, could result in serious detriment in that age bracket.
The refusal of a loan because there are doubts that a consumer has the
capacity to
Increased credit limits
The proposals
contained in option 6.3 should also extend to offers of increased credit
It is proposed
that the same assessment criteria as those outlined above for initial
This option meets Objective 2 and, depending on card issuer strategies and options chosen may meet Objective 3.
This option should be considered in concert with Option 6.4 below.
4.6.4 Option 6.4: Provide relief for consumers by making the debt granted in accordance with Option 6.3, including interest charged.
Appropriate
redress for consumers should be linked to the amount of credit
44
the card issuer
had provided a higher credit limit, the difference between the
This relief would apply to the initial application, and any limit increase whether unsolicited or not. There is already provision in the Code that amounts in excess of those permitted by the Code are unenforceable, which gives a precedent for this proposal. ASIC approved alternative dispute resolution schemes such as the Banking and Financial Services Ombudsman would be able to determine the amount that should reasonably have been granted and make the appropriate orders.
The Banking and
Financial Services Ombudsman, in Bulletin 45, March 2005, sets
There is one
relevant issue which has not been the subject of public discussion, This option meets Objective 2 and, depending on card issuer compliance may also meet Objective 3. How should the court or ADR scheme view an assessment process which relies on all disposable income being available for debt servicing?
4.6.5 Option 6.5: Require card issuers to warn consumers about
Most consumers are
shocked to learn that paying only the minimum repayment
45
suggested that information about the length of time it would take to pay off
their loan
A requirement for
a “health warning” on monthly statements in relation to the time
Credit providers
have noted in the past that their systems currently would not be able
In view of the fact that additional information is included from time to
time on monthly
This requirement has recently been legislated but not commenced in the US and is a recommendation made by the independent reviewer of the UK Banking Code that has been accepted by the Code sponsors.
The US system also proposes a requirement for the card issuer to supply a
toll-free A study undertaken by the US Government Accountability Office found that 57% of consumers interviewed preferred potential customised health warnings over the generic warning required under the Bankruptcy Act. Those who did not carry over a balance from month to month predictably were satisfied with generic disclosures. US card issuers foresaw limited impact by any warning because not all who paid only minimum repayments could afford to pay more. This option may partially meet Objective 2 and meets Objective 3.
Information is sought as to the costs involved in providing personalised information on monthly statements as opposed to prescribed examples of the time it would take to pay out a stated amount owing paying only the minimum repayment, as well as the total amount of interest that would be paid.
4.6.6 Option 6.6: Require card issuers to increase the minimum offers of increased credit limits on current cards.
As seen above, the
United States, UK and Thailand have all required or requested
46 to apply to existing as well as new contracts, which would negatively affect existing cardholders able to make only their current minimum repayments. There is no evidence from the UK as to whether these suggestions have been implemented and, if so, what the response has been. An increased percentage repayment would reduce interest payable and also reduce the period over which a credit card debt could be repaid. Since the major lenders’ minimum repayment averages 2.36%, an appropriate minimum repayment percentage, if this option were to proceed, would be 4.5% - 5%. This percentage would not appear excessive, however, if it were to apply to current contracts, more consumers would be in danger of hardship than previously if their repayments doubled. It is suggested therefore that this apply only to new contracts, as well as existing contracts where an increased limit is offered. This option partially meets Objective 2 and meets Objective 3.
4.7 Recommended option At this stage there is no Government commitment to any one option. Preliminary thoughts are that some degree of regulation is necessary, perhaps coupled with educational strategies. The degree and scope of any regulation would depend to a large degree on responses to this consultation paper and a thorough assessment of arguments, costs and data presented by all parties. 5. Impact analysis
This section will make a preliminary assessment of the foreseeable costs and benefits to the participants in this market.
5.1 Option 1: Maintain the status quo Costs of Option 1
Cost to card issuers It is likely that defaults and write-offs, which have been delayed by the lowering of minimum repayment percentages, will increase in the longer term. There may be some increase in write-offs if organisations such as Debt Free Direct attract affected consumers. It should be noted, however, that financial counsellors and consumer legal centres already negotiate write-offs on consumers’ behalf. In a rising interest rate environment the number of defaults or problems with repayment may be accelerated. Depending on the roll-out and success of financial literacy initiatives, there may be some mitigation of this trend in the longer term. The St. Paul Foundation study suggests that there is likely to be a time lag in any negative effects suffered by financial institutions and their shareholders, but that study does not elaborate on the likely consequences. The St Paul Foundation study, which included card issuers on its committee, estimated that at that time about 25% of all cardholders were experiencing difficulties in paying their credit card debts. Should the number of cardholders with repayment problems in Australia increase substantially to the point where bankruptcy or write-offs were to occur on a large scale it is likely that card portfolios would become less profitable.
47 The costs to card issuers are unquantifiable, as are the potential flow-on effects to shareholders and the economy should the problem increase.
Cost to consumers Disadvantaged
A new generation of disadvantaged consumers will be granted excessive
amounts of A number of cardholders will face long term hardship from unmanageable card debt. Bankruptcies may increase. In extreme cases the financial stresses may result in increased family and health problems. These consumers may lose their homes. The number of consumers involved in this scenario is unquantifiable. Mainstream There should be no immediate impact on mainstream consumers from maintaining the status quo.
Mainstream
consumers are most likely to be affected if card issuer losses in the The number of such consumers and the flow on costs are unquantifiable.
Community impact A further likely consequence if the numbers of affected consumers increase substantially is that a diminution in consumer spending power may cause some businesses to fail. This tends to have a negative impact on consumer confidence, which, in turn affects consumer spending. Cost to governments
Governments will
face increasing demand for their services, both in dealing with Governments would also incur costs from the continuing production of financial literacy materials and consumer awareness campaigns about credit card use. There would be negative public perceptions arising from perceived government inaction with respect to credit card debt, and in response to any increase in taxes to fund increased welfare support.
There would be increased pressure from community organisations for additional funding to assist consumers experiencing hardship.
Cost to community organisations
There would be increased demand for assistance in negotiating with card
issuers to
48 Community organisations may also act in partnership with governments on credit card debt awareness campaigns. Benefits of Option 1
Benefit to card issuers Card issuers would continue to benefit from long term interest repayments by those cardholders who can not pay down their card debts. Depending on the number of defaults and write-offs, the amount of such benefit may be reduced. Profit margins would increase as new generations of consumers entered the card market and shareholders would reap the benefits.
Card issuers would not incur costs associated with changing their assessment systems or in implementing new processes.
Benefit to consumers Disadvantaged In the long term, increased focus on financial literacy as a result of more targeted strategies may prevent a small proportion of vulnerable consumers from taking on unmanageable debt. Take-up of new debt negotiation services may assist a small percentage of such consumers achieve write-offs or reduced repayments. Mainstream This group of consumers who benefit from paying no interest on their cards would continue to benefit from being subsidised by the consumer who pays interest over a long term. This may not continue indefinitely if defaults rise to a degree where additional revenue is sought. Community impact No specific benefit identified. Benefits to governments None identified. Benefits to community organisations None identified. 5.1.1 Evaluation This option would have no positive impact on the problems identified, except for a possible improvement over time in financial literacy for some groups of consumers. How improved financial literacy will impact on the disadvantaged consumers identified is not known at this stage.
A negative impact
would be increasing indebtedness of disadvantaged consumers Reduced spending and increasing bad debt may have a negative effect on communities and the economy generally. The market would continue to favour mainstream cardholders over disadvantaged consumers in the cost of providing a card service.
49
This option would not satisfy government objectives of assisting better decisionmaking, but may increase consumer choice. It would not satisfy the objective of adequately protecting disadvantaged consumers. There would be no impact on competition from this option.
5.2 Option 2: Increased penalties and better enforcement of Costs of Option 2
Cost to card issuers Card issuers would be likely to write off more debt if increasing numbers of consumers were represented. The impact on card issuers would depend on the success of strategies to advise consumers of their rights under the law. Increased staff resources may be required to negotiate consumer relief with consumer agencies or community organisations. Cost to consumers Disadvantaged
There would be a
sizeable majority of affected consumers who would not access
Mainstream These consumers would not be affected by this option in the short term, however, because this option would not bring about systemic change, any costs identified in option 1 would apply.
Community Impact The small number of consumers involved in relation to the whole would make the costs to the community similar to those outlined in option 1. Cost to governments
Governments would
require additional resources to negotiate for consumers with Governments would be required to provide additional funding to consumer organisations to increase their capacity to negotiate on behalf of an increased number of consumers.
50
The additional
expenditure on resources may bring criticism in respect of budget Costs to community organisations Consumer organisations would require increased resources if additional cases were to be taken on. For this to be meaningful in terms of impact, two or three times the current level of staffing would probably be required.
Benefits of Option 2 Benefits to card issuers Card issuers would continue to benefit from the ongoing interest repayments from the majority of affected consumers. Their additional resource costs would have little impact on profit margins. Card issuers would be able to continue their operations without change in respect of applications from new generations of consumers. Benefits to consumers Disadvantaged
Those affected
consumers who were able to obtain assistance because of the Mainstream These consumers would continue to benefit from the use of free credit and free payment service, at least in the short term. Community impact No specific benefit identified.
Benefits to government None identified.
Benefits to community organisations If additional resources were available more consumers could be assisted. 5.2.1 Evaluation
This option would assist a small additional number of consumers to obtain
relief, but The increased costs to government and community organisations may divert funds from other programs.
The government
objectives would not be met as consumer choice would not be
This option would have no impact on competition.
51 5.3 Option 3: Education and information Costs of option 3
Costs to card issuers
There is currently
no requirement for card issuers to educate the public about the Should industry decide to substantially increase financial literacy programs and significant improvements in financial literacy occur, and consumer choices improve as a result of improved disclosures, card issuers may experience a reduction in profits from credit cards. Costs to consumers Should additional costs be incurred by industry as a result of change to the statutory disclosure requirements, this may be passed on to consumers. Any cost to the individual consumer would be small but is unquantifiable at this stage. The cost would be the same for disadvantaged and mainstream consumers. Community impact No costs identified. Costs to governments Costs to government would be from funding additional research (as an example, one project is currently costed at $100,000) and in government resources in developing and administering any future research project and subsequent legislative change. These costs would be met within current budgets.
If specialised, targeted financial literacy programs were to be undertaken,
the cost to Costs to community organisations None identified, unless there was involvement with targeted education programs. If this were to be the case it is most likely that government would be required to provide additional funding.
Benefits of Option 3 Benefits to card issuers Should significant improvements in financial literacy occur, and consumer choices improve as a result of improved disclosures, card issuers may experience a reduction in defaults and write-offs.
52 Benefits to consumers Disadvantaged There is no information available about the benefits to disadvantaged children of school-based financial literacy programs. The research on improved precontractual disclosure provisions will not specifically target the possible outcome for disadvantaged consumers of an improved regime for credit cards. Some anecdotal information could be available from this study, but at this stage any benefits are unknown. Targeted financial literacy education has been proven to have good results for disadvantaged consumers, and could provide benefit for those groups of consumers provided with such programs. This would be a long term benefit for a relatively small number of consumers. Mainstream Mainstream consumers would be the likely beneficiaries of school-based financial literacy programs. Since, in the main, this group manages credit card use well, significant additional benefit would not be expected.
Improved precontractual disclosure would also benefit this group of consumers, but to an unknown extent.
Community impact If there were to be significant widespread benefit in the long term there would be benefit to the community from increased consumer participation and spending. This cannot be predicted and is unquantifiable. Benefits to government
Should school programs and targeted financial literacy programs prove
successful in
Benefits to community groups There may be reduced demand on services in the long term if current and future initiatives were to prove successful. This is unquantifiable. 5.3.1 Evaluation
The success or otherwise of across the board initiatives such as financial
literacy in
While it is likely
that targeted financial literacy initiatives would be reasonably
It does seem
apparent that significant numbers of consumers would not be
53 this way. Benefits would seem to be incremental and very long term and may not be the most cost-effective method of dealing with the identified problem.
5.4 Option 4: Self regulation This option considered to be part of the status quo.
5.5 Option 5: Co-regulation Not considered a viable option. 5.6 Option 6: Regulation There are 6 regulatory options.
5.7 Option 6.1: change the timing of essential information Costs of Option 6.1 Cost to card issuers For internet applications, information supplied by Virgin Money suggests there is no cost to the card issuer. For paper-based systems, it would be a relatively simple and inexpensive process, when those documents are renewed and reviewed for content, to include the information required on the application form. The printing of the form would have been a cost incurred without any such addition. The additional cost would be in the redesign of the form and resetting the print format.
Card issuers
are requested to indicate in their response the likely costs of
Card issuers may
be affected by consumers’ choice of cards in that their more Card issuers with high cost products may find that consumers do not proceed with the application and may therefore lose market share. Cost to consumers Disadvantaged Minimal
Mainstream Minimal
Community impact There should be no negative community impact.
Cost to Governments The cost of developing the legislative requirement as well as the cost of enforcing the provision would be incurred by government. This is core government business and it is unlikely that additional resources would be sought.
54 Cost to community organisations None identified.
Benefits of Option 6.1 Benefit to card issuer Minimal Benefit to consumers Disadvantaged
A proportion of
disadvantaged consumers may be influenced by prominently featured Mainstream Search costs for all consumers would be minimised. Comparability would be enhanced, which may lead to reduced credit card costs. Consumers who are price sensitive would be able to exercise their power of choice appropriately. Community impact
The community
generally would benefit from greater transparency of credit card Benefit to Governments There may be a reduction in the level of complaints dealt with by consumer agencies because consumers may make better choices of cost effective cards.
Benefits to community organisations There may be a reduction in the level of complaints dealt with by community organisations. 5.7.1 Evaluation This option would benefit both those card issuers with competitively priced products and those consumers who, if search costs were lowered, would be price sensitive. This would benefit some disadvantaged and most mainstream consumers, with some flow-on benefit to communities. This option would meet the government objective of assisting consumer choice. Transparency of pricing would have a positive effect on competition.
5.8 Option 6.2: require credit providers to allow consumers to Costs of Option 6.2
Cost to the card issuer
Those card issuers
who have granted credit in excess of that which a consumer
55 if introduced, require changes so that all changes to the application form could be undertaken at that time.
When this issue was canvassed in 2001, none of the card issuers commented on the costs of redesigning the form. The only potential cost identified was that consumers may nominate a higher limit than the card issuer would be prepared to grant and may be dissatisfied with a rejection and, presumably, apply elsewhere Card issuers are requested to indicate in their response the likely costs of redesigning the application form to include the suggested field. Cost to the consumer Disadvantaged None identified for those consumers entering the market who would otherwise be given more credit currently than they would want or can afford. Those who were refused because they nominated too high a limit may well try elsewhere, but if objective measures for assessment are in place as suggested in option 6.3, it is unlikely that they would be successful. Mainstream No costs identified. Mainstream consumers have good financial management skills and manage their cards well. They are likely, therefore, to designate a suitable credit limit and continue to manage that amount appropriately. Community impact None identified. Cost to Governments Government would bear the cost of developing the legislation and enforcing its provisions. This would be funded from existing budgets. Cost to community organisations None identified.
Benefits of Option 6.2 Benefit to card issuers It is likely that, with a manageable credit limit, there would be fewer defaults and write-offs, and a reduced need to use debt collection services.
Low income consumers, who previously would not apply for a credit card because they feared a debt trap, may enter the card market.
Benefit to consumers Disadvantaged
Those consumers entering the market who lack the capacity to successfully
manage
34
“Understanding Personal Debt & Financial Difficulty in Australia”, ANZ Bank and A C Nielson, Nov.2005, p.4.
56 have requested. The amount of interest saved could therefore be significant, but is not ascertainable.
Other low income earners interviewed in relation to their use of payday lenders, were reported to exhibit “ a deep suspicion of credit cards…because their repayment dates were imprecise and they were perceived to be difficult to manage”.35
These consumers
preferred a finite high cost product to credit cards, because of Mainstream No specific benefit identified. Community impact
In the long term, should sufficient disadvantaged consumers apply for
manageable Benefit to Governments Government would experience fewer complaints from consumers experiencing difficulties with credit commitments. There would be reduced demand on welfare services that are government funded.
Benefits to community organisations Community organisations would experience fewer complaints from consumers experiencing difficulties with credit commitments.
5.8.1 Evaluation
The major beneficiaries of this option would be low income and disadvantaged
Governments and community organisations would benefit from a reduced demand for their resources.
Card issuers would have a reduced long term income stream but this may be
offset
35 Consumer Law Centre Victoria Ltd, “Payday lending in Victoria - A research report”, July 2002, p.80.
57 This option would meet the government objectives of assisting consumer choice as well as helping consumers to protect themselves against irresponsible lending by choosing a credit limit that suits their need and capacity to repay. This would be a pro-competitive option as a result of consumers being able to exercise purchasing power.
5.9 Option 6.3: Prohibit the card issuer from providing more substantial hardship. Costs of Option 6.3
Cost to card issuers
One cost to the
card issuer would be in systems change to accommodate any A proposal for revised assessment practices was canvassed in 2001, but this specified that institutions should ask for all financial commitments of the applicant and that they should be assessed on that basis (similar to that now in force in the ACT). At that time the majority of card issuers generally affirmed their commitment to credit scoring as the best predictor of repayment capacity. There was no reference to additional costs that would have been incurred. Responses to the Victorian Credit Review did not provide any information on costs. The cost of adjusting a computerised assessment system is not known to those outside the industry. Details of such costs are requested below.
Card issuers
are requested to indicate any additional costs arising from this
Assessment of an appropriate credit limit for new applicants or increased limits on the basis that the applicant must be able to pay it off within 7 years, may result in reduced interest payable over time since the debt would theoretically be paid off more quickly. However, this would be offset in the short to medium term by the higher monthly minimum repayments that would ensure repayment in a shorter timeframe under this option, or that would be required under option 6.6, if this is introduced. It may be further offset by increased numbers of disadvantaged consumers applying for cards if they were seen by this group of consumers as a credit option that would not lead to problem debt.
58
Card issuers may choose to end the cross subsidisation of those consumers who pay no interest and therefore receive a free payment service and a period of interest free credit by requiring that group of consumers to pay for the service provided.
In a report issued
by the Prices Surveillance Authority (PSA) in 1992, a number of
Card issuers are requested to assess any reduction of interest that may result from the implementation of option 3, based on the difference between current assessments and minimum repayments and those which would be required as a result of this option.
Card issuers are also requested to detail the costs of training and compliance activities.
Cost to consumers Disadvantaged
There should be no
costs for these consumers. There would be no change in Mainstream Those who are able to comfortably service the amount of credit granted should not be affected since they clearly have the capacity to repay amounts in excess of the minimum repayment requirement, or they do not use credit to the limit given. This group is unlikely to be affected by any changes to practices flowing from requirements that capacity to repay should rely on income, since they would have made rational choices of product and lender to access a product they can afford and would consider an offer of a limit increase in the same manner.
Community impact
It is not clear
that there would be any loss to card issuers over time that would impact
If card issuers suffered loss and were not prepared to recoup that loss as
suggested
36 Prices Surveillance Authority, “Inquiry into credit card interest rates”, October 1992, p96
59 smaller dividends to shareholders. Depending on the degree of loss this could have a minor impact on the economy with loss of spending power, or minor community impact through less access to services. Cost to Governments Depending on card issuers’ conduct following implementation of this option, Governments may be involved in enforcement activities if it was found that card issuers were continuing to avoid the requirements. Any costs are unascertainable at this time, but would require the use of internal compliance and legal resources as well as possibly a non-government Counsel. Courts would also incur costs in hearing cases brought for contraventions of the requirements.
Cost to community organisations None identified. Benefits of Option 6.3
Benefit to card issuers Default numbers should be reduced in respect of new applicants and those who accept higher limits. There would also be a reduction in the resources needed to deal with “high maintenance” accounts, which require repeated contact for repayment or which are assigned to debt collectors. There is currently no reliable data to indicate the number of such consumers or the amount of credit in default that could be attributed to those that currently “slip through” the system. Benefit to consumers Disadvantaged
There should be a significantly reduced percentage of those consumers
entering the
Those consumers
who might otherwise have been granted excessive amounts of
37 A C Nielson/ANZ Bank “Understanding Personal Debt and Financial Difficulty in Australia”, November 2005.
60
Those who might
otherwise be granted more than they can afford would have less
Mainstream No specific benefit identified.
Community impact A number of disadvantaged consumers would have greater spending power, which would provide support for local businesses. There may be a reduction in destructive social behaviour if financial stresses on families are reduced. Benefit to Governments Government might expect fewer complaints from consumers about their own or their dependents’ credit card debts.
There may be reduced demand on other government services such as provided by housing and health portfolios.
Funding provided by governments to consumer organisations could be better targeted to allow organisations to help consumers in need of assistance for reasons other than unmanageable debt caused by irresponsible lending. Benefit to community organisations There should be a reduction in the number of consumer complaints and consequent negotiations with card issuers, as well as a reduction in the number of applications to the Tribunal or the BFSO for relief that are brought by consumers with the assistance of community organisations. Consumer organisations’ resources could be targeted to allow those organisations to help consumers in need of assistance for reasons other than unmanageable debt caused by irresponsible lending.
5.9.1 Evaluation
Low income and
disadvantaged consumers who are entering the credit market as
61
Lifetime credit
card debt will be avoided. There would be a reduced likelihood that The current capacity of credit providers to check an applicant’s credit commitments is limited by the credit reporting system which would not give a full picture. Those consumers who did not honestly disclose their commitments when these were requested, would not benefit from a more stringent assessment, and card issuers should not be called to account for wrongly assessing such consumers.
The credit
reporting system is currently being reviewed by the Australian Law Reform
Mainstream consumers may lose the subsidisation of their credit card by disadvantaged consumers.
Card issuers will
forego the benefit of long term interest repayments from new
This option would meet the objective of protecting a significant number of current and future cardholders from irresponsible lending by, firstly, making it a positive requirement that can attract a penalty and, secondly, providing a guide as to what would be considered by regulators in assessing whether card issuers had contravened the prohibition.
There would be a positive impact on competition from any reduction in cross subsidisation.
5.10 Option 6.4: Provide relief for consumers by making the amount granted in accordance with Option 6.3, including interest charged. Costs of Option 6.4 Cost to card issuers Card issuers would need to ensure compliance with the requirements and to educate their officers and representatives on any new systems. It should be recognised, however, that changes are routinely made to systems requiring internal compliance and education, so that this should not be an unusual or exorbitant cost.
Any cardholder
debt which is unenforceable would be a cost to the card issuer,
62 Card issuers are requested to indicate costs associated with this option.
As consumer
redress would rely on an examination of the credit limit allocated in
Card issuers are requested to assess the cost of accessing a consumer’s application form and forwarding it to a relevant agency on request. Since it is unlikely that the number of requests for this information could be anticipated, costs on a per unit basis would be sufficient. Cost to consumers Disadvantaged Costs may be passed on to all consumers via interest rates or fees. If a fee was imposed then all cardholders whose contract had a capacity to charge new fees would be affected. However, in view of an increasingly competitive card market, it is likely that any passed on costs would be small. Mainstream If fees were imposed, or the interest free period reduced or cancelled, there would be a cost to this group of consumers. This cost can not be quantified. Community impact Any cost related to this option would have little community impact. Cost to Governments Governments would bear the cost of enforcement action for systemic problems. It is likely, however, that penalty provisions in contrast to the current re-opening provisions, would deter systemic abuses. There may initially be an increase in inquiries from consumers as to their rights. Cost to community organisations There may initially be an increase in inquiries from consumers about their rights. Benefits of Option 6.4
Benefits to card issuers Those card issuers who were not involved in enforcement actions would gain an improved public image. Benefits to consumers Disadvantaged
Cardholders who were granted excessive amounts of credit could obtain relief
from
Mainstream No specific benefit identified
63
Community impact The reduced likelihood of overcommitment which would flow from the prospect of penalties, as well as a reduction in indebtedness of those consumers who had been incorrectly assessed, suggests that more consumers would have disposable income to spend in their local communities. There would be a positive impact on social cohesiveness and a reduction in family breakdown. Benefits to Governments Governments would benefit from reduced complaints and requests for assistance with credit card-related matters.
Complaints received would be more easily resolved since there would be a standard for assessment by which the consumer’s credit limit could be measured.
Demands for government funded services such as those provided by housing, health and community services, may be reduced.
Benefits to community organisations Community organisations would benefit from a reduced number of credit card complaints and requests for assistance. This category of complaint forms a significant proportion of community organisations’ workload. The complaints received would be more easily resolved since there would be a standard for assessment by which consumers’ credit limits could be measured. 5.10.1 Evaluation
The major benefit
of this option would be in it providing an incentive to card issuers to
The cost would
be shared by all card issuers in ensuring compliance with
This option
provides additional motivation for card issuers to lend responsibly and
Appropriate redress mechanisms are essential to the capacity of consumers to exercise market power. This option is therefore pro-competitive.
5.11 Option 6.5: Require card issuers to warn consumers about the effect of paying only the minimum repayments
Costs of Option 6.5
Cost to card issuers This issue has been canvassed with credit providers on two occasions: first in 2001 and again, in the Consumer Credit Review conducted by Victoria. In 2001 industry generally responded by questioning the need for and benefits of a “health warning”. No potential costs to industry were provided at that time. 64
In 2005, in
response to the Victorian Consumer Credit Review issues paper where Costs to card issuers are assumed to consist of system adjustments to print a prescribed warning with specified examples on the monthly statement, as well as a telephone-based response capacity for more personalised information. Costs of the latter could be reduced by a single source providing the service for all card issuers if agreement could be reached between the lenders. Card issuers are requested to indicate the likely costs if including a prescribed warning on statements and an industry funded centralised telephone information system.
Cost to consumers Disadvantaged Depending on the level of costs indicated by card issuers, these may be passed on to consumers in interest rates or fees. Mainstream Depending on the method of cost recovery, if this is passed on to consumers, mainstream consumers may also be subject to increased fees.
Community impact It is unlikely that any fee passed on to consumers would impact greatly on consumers and would therefore have little community impact. Cost to Governments There would be a small cost to Government in developing the requirements for such disclosure. This would be considered part of its currently funded activities and would not therefore constitute an additional cost. Cost to community groups No cost identified. Benefits of Option 6.5
Benefit to card issuers If card issuers are correct in their assertions that most credit card problems are due to sudden change in consumers’ circumstances, or that consumers are not using the cards responsibly, a warning such as that proposed may assist both categories of cardholders to consider the dangers of long term indebtedness and to avoid this by reduced use of their cards and early attempts to pay down debt before the credit limit is reached. The likely benefit cannot be quantified. Benefit to consumers Disadvantaged
Consumers who were
not aware of the dangers of paying the minimum repayment on
38 The Report of the Consumer Credit Review, Victoria, p.151.
65
information which seems to impact strongly on those who have not been
exposed to An intangible benefit would be an enhanced understanding of financial matters, contributing to the increased financial literacy of this group of consumers. Mainstream There is no identified benefit for this group of consumers. Community Impact This option could increase social and financial participation for those consumers able to respond to the warning.
Benefit to Governments Government could expect some reduction in the number of requests for assistance from consumers who were able to respond to the warning. This may have a positive impact on government resources, however, the benefit is unquantifiable. Benefit to community organisations Community organisations could also expect some reduction in the number of requests for assistance. Since credit card debt constitutes a significant proportion of consumer credit and financial counselling work, the benefit may significant in the longer term if this option were to be implemented in concert with other options. The benefit is not, however, quantifiable. 5.11.1 Evaluation The major beneficiaries of this option would be disadvantaged consumers who have not yet reached the credit limit and who may have capacity to pay down their card. New cardholders should have limits appropriate to their income, however, this would benefit them by encouraging them to pay off as much of their balance as possible and would increase financial literacy.
Card issuers would bear the cost of providing the additional information, as
well as a
This option would
protect existing consumers from the consequences of irresponsible
The effect on competition would be neutral.
5.12 Option 6.6: Require card issuers to increase the minimum repayment percentage for new credit card contracts and for offers of increased credit limits on current cards.
Costs of Option 6.6 Cost to card issuers 66
This is not an option which has been canvassed previously. It is estimated that there would be short term and long term costs associated with this option.
The short term
costs would arise from the systems change necessary to deal with Long term costs would arise as a result of consumers paying down their accounts over a shorter period with a consequent reduction in interest. This may, however, also be accounted for under previous options, if introduced. It is likely that increased minimum repayments from new cardholders and those who elect to accept a limit increase would offset this cost. It is not possible to quantify these costs. Card issuers are requested to provide estimated short term and long term costs of this proposal. Cost to consumers Disadvantaged
Consumers entering
new contracts would be required to pay a higher minimum
Mainstream Those consumers who pay the entire balance would not be affected. Those existing consumers who have a small but ongoing balance are unlikely to require or agree to a credit limit increase. New applicants in this category are highly likely to be financially literate and would understand the implication of a higher minimum repayment requirement. Any costs would be minimal. Community impact No specific costs identified. Cost to governments No identified costs apart from the development and drafting of legislation. Cost to community organisations None identified. Benefits of Option 6.6 Benefit to card issuers There would be increased income from new cards and limit increases. This is unquantifiable. Benefit to consumers Disadvantaged Those consumers entering the market who paid only the minimum repayment would pay less interest and repay debts over a shorter period. Mainstream No benefits for mainstream consumers identified.
67
Community impact Reduced indebtedness of disadvantaged consumers would allow local business to be supported and would reduce social effects of debt problems. Benefit to governments There may be a reduced number of consumers seeking assistance with unmanageable debt. Benefit to community organisations There may be a reduced number of consumers seeking assistance with unmanageable debt. 5.12.1 Evaluation The major benefit from this option would flow to new cardholders, whose interest repayments over the long term would be reduced. The effect on card issuers is less certain and would depend on the number of new cardholders entering the market, and the take-up of increased limits by existing cardholders to offset any long term losses of interest payments.
On balance, the benefit to the individuals and the flow-on effect to the community of improved financial circumstances for a significant number of consumers would appear to outweigh the costs to card issuers. This option would work in tandem with option 6.3 to meet the objective of protecting consumers from irresponsible lending practices by ensuring those consumers were not subject to a lifetime debt.
This option would have no impact on competition.
6. Consultation The proposals in their current form have not been the subject of consultation. However, there have been a number of initiatives since 2000 which have involved consultation with consumers, card issuers and community organisations in relation to credit card issues and proposals for dealing with the perceived problems.
They are:
• A New South Wales Consumer Credit Phone-in in November 2000; • A Consumer Credit Round Table Conference in February 2001; • A New South Wales card issuer research project in 2001; • A consultation paper in July-August 2001; • The Consumer Credit Review conducted by Consumer Affairs Victoria between 2005 and 2007. The Phone-in allowed consumers the opportunity to air their concerns.
The Round
Table Conference brought those concerns to the industry.
At that Conference,
The consultation paper
proposed regulatory measures to deal with the problems, based on
consideration of
68 The project did not proceed further at that time. There were, however, responses from industry and consumer organisations to the proposals at that time, some of the proposals being similar in substance to those outlined above, but not necessarily the express requirements proposed. A separate but relevant review was undertaken by Consumer Affairs Victoria covering a wide range of credit-related concerns, including responsible lending. To the extent that there is similarity to the scope of this consultation paper the responses of interested parties to the Victorian review to the options presented here are outlined below:
Option 6.1. This was not previously canvassed in regulatory proposals. However, in recent times there has been considerable discussion of the usefulness of disclosure material athe optimal timing of any disclosure. A research project is currently under way and will test the likely benefits of providing relevant information at an earlier stage. Option 6.2. A significant number of case studies identified in consumer advocates’ submissions have highlighted the fact that consumers have been given more credit than they wanted, in some cases these consumers having noted on the application form the amount required even though there was no field on the form for this to be supplied. Such requests were not honoured.
This option was
raised in 2001. Credit unions supported the proposal while banks claimed it
was their prerogative to set the limit. Some suggested that consumers
would be offended by not being granted the (higher) amount sought. This
would not
appear logical since consumers generally nominate the amount of credit
required in The Victorian Consumer Credit Review raised this issue in relation to unsolicited credit card offers and credit card limit increases, with an option that credit providers should be permitted to make provisional offers to their customers, but the customer would have to positively elect the credit limit or increased limit they require. Credit providers argued that they have a commercial incentive to adopt prudent lending practices where, as with credit cards, there is no security and the amount outstanding does not amortise. However, the concern here is not that consumers will default and the credit provider will lose money, but that the consumer will be trapped into a never ending debt cycle. Option 6.3. This was previously proposed in a different form in which card issuers were requiredto collect all financial information on applicants’ income, expenditure and credit commitments and ensure these were used to assess the applicant’s capacity to repay.
These proposals were welcomed by community organisations whose clients, if properly assessed, should never have received the limits they had been granted.
Credit unions generally agreed with the proposals.
Banks were opposed, citing credit scoring as a more reliable indicator of
capacity to
69
positive reporting system. This latter issue is acknowledged, however, the credit reporting system is currently under review, as recommended by the Wallis inquiry. The Australian Law Reform Commission has proposed that the information available to credit providers should be expanded to include information about current accounts, the dates the accounts were opened and closed, and the credit limits of each. These measures, if adopted, would provide the information necessary for credit providers to more readily assess a consumer’s capacity to repay.
The claims as to the reliability of credit scoring are not accepted. Credit
scoring is at
The Victorian
Credit Review put forward an option to place a positive obligation on Consumer advocates were generally supportive of this option but were divided as to which model should be used to define an adequate assessment.
The Australian Bankers’ Association opposed the ACT model, stating there was
no
The Review notes that this option reflects principles that the Banking and Financial Services Ombudsman applies to maladministration issues.
Option 6.4. This was not previously canvassed in the New South Wales proposals and is a relief and enforcement proposal that has parallels with requirements and relief mechanisms already in the Code. The Victorian Credit Review option suggested that legislation should provide explicitly for a remedy that the credit contract is unenforceable to the extent that it imposes a liability on the consumer beyond that which is appropriate. This also reflects the principles and practices of the Banking and Financial Services Ombudsman in its consideration of maladministration issues. Option 6.5. This was previously canvassed in the NSW paper but in an expanded form. Community advocates and credit unions supported the proposal. Banks did not, citing the cost of systems that would be required for a personalised warning.
In submissions to
the Victorian Credit Review, the Consumer Credit Legal Centre
70 were offered. The warning should focus on the time it would take to pay off the account if paying only the minimum repayment.
The Australian Bankers’ Association noted that industry currently provides warning to consumers when offering increased limits as to how their minimum repayment would be increased by accepting the new limit, and that if their personal circumstances have changed they should not accept the new limit. The “warning” does not address the time required to pay out the new limit.
The proposal in this paper has been refined to reduce system costs and to provide personalised information in a more cost effective way.
Option 6.6.
This has not
previously been canvassed but regulatory responses to similar issues in
the US, UK and Thailand have resulted in
either regulation or guidelines to raise the Consumer advocates overseas have raised concerns about raising the minimum repayment percentage on existing contracts which could impact negatively on consumers’ capacity to repay, however, option 6.6 does not suggest that existing contracts should be affected.
In general, the banking industry has denied the need for any changes, referring to low default rates and the fact that the majority of consumers manage their cards well.
6.1 Future consultation process This paper will be released for comment for a period of six weeks, following which the responses to the options and the costs involved in implementing those options will be considered in formulating a decision making regulatory impact statement. 7. Evaluation and Review The options set out above have been targeted to address the problems experienced by consumers and aim to rectify the regulatory failure identified above. They, in part, reflect overseas initiatives that respond to similar problems.
The limitations of disclosure and education are discussed above, as are self
regulatory mechanisms. This paper
suggests that they are not viable alternatives to The costs of these proposals are not available at this time. This paper requests that costs be supplied by industry so that a cost/benefit analysis can assist in formulating the final recommendations. Any legislation resulting from the final recommendations would include a date by which the legislation is to be reviewed. This is commonly three or five years. In order that any review should be meaningful, data collection sources will be contacted to ensure that appropriate data can be collected and aggregated.
71 |
|
|